UBC Theses and Dissertations

UBC Theses Logo

UBC Theses and Dissertations

The demand for milk in British Columbia : estimation and implications Kassam, Shinan N. 1991

Your browser doesn't seem to have a PDF viewer, please download the PDF to view this item.

Item Metadata

Download

Media
831-UBC_1991_A6_7 K38.pdf [ 4.47MB ]
Metadata
JSON: 831-1.0098531.json
JSON-LD: 831-1.0098531-ld.json
RDF/XML (Pretty): 831-1.0098531-rdf.xml
RDF/JSON: 831-1.0098531-rdf.json
Turtle: 831-1.0098531-turtle.txt
N-Triples: 831-1.0098531-rdf-ntriples.txt
Original Record: 831-1.0098531-source.json
Full Text
831-1.0098531-fulltext.txt
Citation
831-1.0098531.ris

Full Text

THE DEMAND FOR MILK IN BRITISH COLUMBIA: ESTIMATION AND IMPLICATIONS by SHINAN N. K A S S A M B.Sc.(Agr.), The University of British Columbia, 1989 A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF SCIENCE in THE FACULTY OF GRADUATE STUDIES (Department of Agricultural Economics) We accept this thesis as conforming to the required standard THE UNIVERSITY OF BRITISH COLUMBIA July 1991 © Shinan N. Kassam, 1991 In presenting this thesis in partial fulfilment of the requirements for an advanced degree at the University of British Columbia, I agree that the Library shall make it freely available for reference and study. I further agree that permission for extensive copying of this thesis for scholarly purposes may be granted by the head of my department or by his or her representatives. It is understood that copying or publication of this thesis for financial gain shall not be allowed without my written permission. Department of AunRX* ^CofO>. The University of British Columbia Vancouver, Canada Date r T O L M I f. l^'W DE-6 (2/88) ABSTRACT In this paper, we estimate dynamic versions of the Almost Ideal Demand System and the Linear Expenditure System in order to obtain an estimate of the demand elasticity for milk in British Columbia. This parameter has, to our knowledge, never been estimated for one province, but given the ongoning interest by the B.C. dairy industry in obtaining a larger allocation of Market Share Quota (MSQ), which is now allocated as a function of fluid milk consumption, it is timely to estimate the elasticity of demand for milk in British Columbia. Many have argued that the retail price of milk in B.C. is too high, especially when compared to prices in other western provinces, as well as the neighbouring State of Washington. The argument is that significant increases in consumption, and thereby increased allocation of MSQ could be achieved through decreases in prices. However, this depends upon the elasticity of demand which we herein estimate. Our estimate of the elasticity of demand for milk in British Columbia is -0.33, as estimated from the dynamic Almost Ideal System, and -0.40 from the dynamic Linear Expenditure System. We note that the dynamic Linear Expenditure System estimated in this study was statistically significant and met all theoretical restrictions, in particular quasi-concavity of the utility function at each observation point. We note, however, that this elasticity estimate may be interpreted as a short run estimate owing to our limited time frame for analysis. Clearly, with an elasticity estimate in the order of -0.40, "significant" increases in consumption cannot be achieved solely through decreases in prices. This paper, however, does more than simply relay elasticity estimates, for it also provides tips and techniques for estimating demand systems such as those estimated in this paper. These strategies are typically not found in textbooks or journal articles, and as such can be of great use to those estimating demand systems for the first time. ii In addition, this study makes use of a regional data source that has previously been unavailable to applied economists. Those who have attempted to estimate the demand for milk regionally have found that Statistics Canada does not publish regional consumption figures for most commodities. This is particularly true for the consumption of beverages in British Columbia. The data for this study were obtained privately and statistically represent bi-monthly sales of beverages in British Columbia. Thus, this paper is the first to estimate the demand for milk in British Columbia by using a demand systems approach employing data obtained from a private source (i.e. not Statistics Canada or other public sector organisations). iii TABLE OF CONTENTS ABSTRACT ii LIST OF TABLES vi LIST OF FIGURES vii ACKNOWLEDGEMENT viii 1.0 INTRODUCTION 1 1.1 BACKGROUND 2 1.2 PROBLEM STATEMENT 3 1.3 OBJECTIVE 5 1.4 RESEARCH PROCEDURE 5 2.0 THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS 7 2.1 REVIEW OF PREVIOUS STUDIES 7 2.2 RELEVANT THEORY 10 2.3 FUNCTIONAL FORM 12 2.3.1 THE STATIC AIDS 13 2.3.2 THE DYNAMIC AIDS ....16 2.3.3 THE DYNAMIC LINEAR EXPENDITURE SYSTEM 17 2.3.4 CURVATURE CONDITIONS ...18 2.3.5 STANDARD ERRORS FOR UNESTIMATED PARAMETERS 19 3.0 EMPIRICAL MODEL 21 3.1 ESTIMATION OF THE AIDS/LES 21 3.1.1 DATA CONSTRUCTION FOR SYSTEMS ESTIMATION 21 3.2 SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION 22 3.2.1 DATA CONSTRUCTION-SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION ...23 3.3 DATA SOURCES 23 3.4 DEBUGGING PROCEDURES FOR AIDS/LES ESTIMATION 27 4.0 RESULTS & IMPLICATIONS 29 4.1 RESULTS FROM STATIC AIDS ESTIMATION 29 4.2 RESULTS FROM DYNAMIC AIDS/DYNAMIC LES ESTIMATION 34 4.3 RESULTS FROM SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION , 42 4.4 IMPLICATIONS 42 5.0 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS .47 5.1 SUMMARY .47 5.2 CONCLUSIONS .48 5.3 RECOMMENDATIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH 49 BIBLIOGRAPHY 51 i V TABLE OF CONTENTS cont. APPENDICES: APPENDIX 1 - DERIVATION OF PRICE ELASTICITIES FOR THE AIDS 53 APPENDIX 2 - SHAZAM PROGRAM FOR A 5 GOOD AIDS SYSTEM 54 APPENDIX 3 - OWN PRICE / EXPENDITURE ELASTICITIES-STATIC AIDS 56 APPENDIX 4 - CROSS PRICE AND TEMPERATURE ELASTICITIES FROM THE STATIC AIDS 58 APPENDIX 5 - DATA USED IN SYSTEM /SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION 64 V LIST OF TABLES TABLE 1 - COMMERCIAL (PER CAPITA) SALES OF MILK IN B.C TABLE 2 - ESTIMATED PARAMETERS FROM THE STATIC AIDS ESTIMATION TABLE 3 - EXPENDITURE AND OWN PRICE ELASTICITIES - STATIC AIDS TABLE 4 - ESTIMATED PARAMETERS FROM THE DYNAMIC AIDS ESTIMATION TABLE 5 - ESTIMATED PARAMETERS FROM THE DYNAMIC LES ESTIMATION TABLE 6 - EXPENDITURE AND OWN PRICE ELASTICITIES - DYNAMIC AIDS TABLE 7 - EXPENDITURE AND OWN PRICE ELASTICITIES - DYNAMIC LES TABLE 8 - PRICE & INCOME ELASTICITIES FOR MILK-COMPARISON WITH PREVIOUS STUDIES vi LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE 1 - TEMPERATURE ELASTICITIES (COFFEE.TEA, MILK) VS. TIME 33 FIGURE 2 - TEMPERATURE ELASTICITIES (SOFT DRINKS, JUICE) VS. TIME 34 FIGURE 3 - COFFEE EQUATION RESIDUALS VS. TIME 40 FIGURE 4 - SOFT DRINK EQUATION RESIDUALS VS. TIME 40 FIGURE 5 - MILK EQUATION RESIDUALS VS. TIME 41 FIGURE 6 - TEA EQUATION RESIDUALS VS. TIME 41 vi i ACKNOWLEDGEMENT In the name of Allah (God), The Most Beneficent, The Most Merciful. Many thanks and praise are owed to my mentor Rick Barichello, and to committee members Tim Hazledine and Terence J. Wales. Their time and effort did not go unnoticed and were much appreciated. Helpful comments and suggestions were also received from Mary Bohman. In addition to the help and guidance from my committee members and others, the completion of this thesis would not have been possible without the 10:15 and 3:20 coffee breaks in the reading room, the dart games at the Grad Centre and the Golf Club, and lastly the good humour of my office mates. The quantity and quality of the pranks being pulled off in the office made coming to school something to look forward to, even in times of despair. v i i i 10 INTRODUCTION Dairy products, in particular fluid milk, are a key component of the food basket in Canada, as they account for approximately sixteen percent of total food and beverage purchases. Moreover, the dairy industry remains a key sector of the economy, accounting for thirty three percent of farm cash receipts in Quebec, eighteen percent in Ontario, and approximately twenty one percent of the receipts in British Columbia. In spite of the importance attached to the Dairy industry, there has been little recent research on identifying variables affecting dairy product consumption and then estimating their effect. The majority of previous research has been focussed on a national level using data from the 1970's or earlier, and while national consumption studies are useful, they do not reflect peculiarities which are specific to each provincial market. This is particularly true in the case of the British Columbia milk market. During the past three years, British Columbians have on average been paying fifteen percent more for their milk than consumers in the main centres of Calgary, Edmonton, Saskatoon, Regina, and Winnipeg. In fact, B.C. fluid milk prices are among the highest of any jurisdiction in North America. In addition, a major proportion of B.C.'s population lives less than twenty five miles from the U.S. border, where they can purchase U.S. milk at a price considerably lower than that charged in British Columbia. Given these price differentials, there have been questions raised from time to time about the appropriateness of pricing policy for fluid milk in B.C.. Notwithstanding the consumer interest in lower milk prices, there has been an argument put forward that the milk industry, including both producers and processors, would be better off as a result of the increase in fluid milk sales induced by a lowering of prices at the retail level. Given that B.C. has, on more than one occasion, expressed its dissatisfaction with the allocation of industrial milk quota, there is an added reason to seek the most advantageous pricing arrangement for fluid milk in B.C.. 1 The argument, however, depends crucially upon a parameter of demand, the own-price elasticity. This parameter has not previously been estimated for B.C., and as such it is both timely and useful to estimate a demand function for fluid milk in B.C.. This is the objective of this study. 1.1 BACKGROUND There exist two distinct markets for milk in British Columbia and Canada. Of all the milk produced, approximately sixty five percent is used in the industrial milk market, where it is manufactured into milk products such as butter, cheese, yoghurt, and ice cream, while thirty five percent is used in the fluid milk market (table milk and fresh cream). The production of industrial milk in British Columbia, as in the rest of Canada (excluding Newfoundland) is currently regulated by a national agreement, The National Milk Marketing Plan. Under the auspices of this agreement, the Canadian Milk Supply Management Committee sets national quota levels (Market Share Quota) for industrial milk and allocates this quota provincially on the basis of historical production patterns. The exception is British Columbia, who had negotiated a special membership provision in November 1984 after giving notice to opt out of the plan in 1983-1984. The provision, which is unique to B.C., allows for B.C.'s provincial market share quota (MSQ) to be determined on the basis of a 35/65 rule, i.e. B.C.'s MSQ within any dairy year will be based on 35/65th's of its average consumption of fluid milk over the previous two calendar years, calculated on the basis of butterfat. However, a companion provision provides that in years in which global Canadian MSQ does not increase, B.C.'s increase in MSQ will be restricted to a maximum of 0.1% of the global Canadian MSQ for that year. Production levels of fluid milk, however, are the responsibility of the provincial marketing boards who administer pricing formulae, quota policies and other regulations. The provincal boards oversee all aspects of the fluid milk market and aim for self-sufficiency in both table milk and 2 fresh cream within their respective borders, while providing a stable environment for local dairy industries. In 1986, there were 1183 dairy farms in British Columbia, of which 846 farms (72%) generated sales of over $100,000 per farm. Moreover, dairy cash receipts, as a percentage of total farm cash receipts, ranks first in B.C. (approximately 21%). In contrast, Canadian dairy cash receipts as a percentage of total farm receipts (approximately 14%) ranks second behind cattle and calves. Considering that one in every five dollars of farm receipts in B.C. (and one in every seven dollars in Canada) comes from dairying, it is not hard to see why the dairy industry is economically and politically important. In 1989, the dairy industry in Canada accounted for over 3 billion dollars in farm cash receipts. But, as Barichello (1980) points out, the magnitude of this number hides the inequality of distribution among various provinces. Of this three billion dollars in 1989, Quebec's share was approximately thirty seven percent, Ontario was second with thirty five percent, and Alberta and B.C. were equal with almost eight percent. The current allocation of MSQ to British Columbia, where approximately twelve percent of the national population resides, is approximately 3.8% of the national total. However, Quebec and Ontario combined have approximately eighty percent of the national MSQ. With such an unequal distribution, it is not surprising to find strong debate surrounding these seemingly arbitrary provincial allocations. 1.2 PROBLEM STATEMENT The current allocation of national MSQ quota is not the only source of discontent in the industry. Given B.C.'s status in the National Milk Marketing Plan, expansion in B.C.'s MSQ is limited to increased consumption of fluid milk, given that B.C. decides not to opt out of the existing national plan. However, per capita sales of 3 many dairy products, milk in particular, offer little growth and in some cases even decline. This is illustrated in table 1. Table 1 - Commercial (per capita) sales of milk in B.C. Whole 2 % All B.C. Milk % Milk % Milk % Pop. % Period (l/cap) change (l/cap) change (l/cap) change (000) change 1978 44.70 - 53.90 - 76.00 - 2542.3 -1979 45.10 +0.89 56.40 +4.64 78.00 +2.63 2589.4 1.85 1980 44.50 -1.33 57.40 +1.77 78.10 +0.13 2666.0 2.96 1981 43.10 -3.15 58.10 +1.22 77.30 -1.02 2744.2 2.93 1982 39.70 -7.89 57.30 -1.38 73.30 -5.17 2787.7 1.59 1983 36.30 -8.56 55.60 -2.97 69.00 -5.87 2813.8 0.94 1984 33.40 -7.99 55.90 +0.54 66.20 -4.06 2847.7 1.20 1985 30.90 -7.49 56.60 +1.25 64.40 -2.72 2870.1 0.79 1986 29.60 -4.21 57.70 +1.94 63.90 -0.78 2889.0 0.66 1987 27.80 -6.08 57.80 +0.17 62.40 -2.35 2925.0 1.25 1988 26.30 -5.40 58.00 +0.35 61.20 -1.92 2980.2 1.89 1989 24.30 -7.60 58.00 +0.00 59.50 -2.78 3053.3 2.45 TOTAL -45.64 - +7.61 - -21.71 - +20.10 Source: The Dairy Review, various issues. Apart from decreased sales due to the ongoing health consciousness attitude, some have argued that the product (milk) in B.C. retails at too high a price when compared to what the producer is paid. These prices have not been set at this level by an explicity policy, but rather by a formula devised in 1955. In 1989, the B.C. farmer received approximately 59c per litre for his product, yet the product retailed for just over $1 per litre. This is an enormous difference (over 70%), and is quite surprising when we find 4 that discounts in the order of twenty to twenty five percent are being given to large accounts by processors (Shelford, 1988). Some, such as Shelford, have argued that there exists "excess fat" in the industry, and whether or not it accrues to either processor or retailer, or whether higher prices to low volume accounts helps to meet the demand of large retailers is unclear. In any event, it is a disturbing issue, and one that ties in directly with the desire for more MSQ quota in B.C.. As you may recall, MSQ quota in B.C. is allocated on the basis of fluid milk consumption, which is partially a function of its own price. It is quite clear that if the farm-retail margins were lowered, the demand/consumption of milk would increase. But, by how much? We attempt to answer this question in the chapters which herein follow. 1.3 OBJECTIVE The objective of this study is to estimate the demand for fluid milk in British Columbia, using both a systems approach as well as a single equation method. The resulting own and cross price elasticities will then be compared with estimates from previous studies done on selected areas of Canada, those done on a Canada wide basis, as well as U.S. studies. The implications of these elasticities will then be assessed in light of both past and present concerns exhibited by the B.C. dairy industry. 1.4 RESEARCH PROCEDURE Chapter 1 has served to provide the objective and importance of this study. Chapter 2, which follows, will provide theoretical considerations, such as the theory relevant to the problem at hand, as well as a review of related studies and what can be learnt from them. Chapter three provides the empirical model and data base used in this study, and chapter 4 serves to report the results of the estimation and their 5 implications. Lastly, chapter 5 summarizes all findings, provides conclusions and offers recommendations for future research. 6 ?.0 THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS 2.1 REVIEW OF PREVIOUS STUDIES As has previously been mentioned, studies on the demand for milk are, if anything, sparse. A thorough literature survey uncovered no relevant studies on the B.C. demand for milk, but did result in the finding of papers on the demand for milk in other parts of Canada, Canada as a whole, and select areas of the United States The purpose of this section is not to dwell upon these studies, nor to provide a comprehensive critique or assessment, but rather to report the various models and techniques employed, what can be learnt from them and the resulting own price, cross price, and income elasticities. The latter will be reported towards the end of the report. If for nothing else, these estimates should prove to be useful for comparison purposes. The most recent estimate on the demand for milk in Canada was obtained by Goddard and Tielu (1988), and focussed upon Ontario. The model employed was a two stage demand system with milk, soft drinks, apple juice, tomato juice, and orange juice constituting the "market" for beverages. An attraction of the model estimated by Goddard and Tielu was the inclusion of advertising expenditures, as well as demographic variables such as percentages of the Ontario population falling between certain age groups, and the average age of the consumer in Ontario. Unfortunately, however, the method and use of data are questionable. This is not to say that the authors were negligent in their search for data, for we encountered many of the same problems ourselves in finding data specific to the region being analyzed. More often than not, Statistics Canada's data set on consumption estimates for provinces is either classified or not collected. As a result, estimates of consumption for many commodities in Canada are national in scope. Realizing this obvious drawback, the authors simply constructed consumption figures by pro-rating national figures on the basis of population. Evidence, however, suggests that this is simply not reasonable. Take for instance the British Columbia soft drink market. Figures on annual soft drink 7 sales provided by the Canadian Soft drink association show that in 1988, B.C. consumed 8.7% of Canadian soft drink sales, while in 1989, this figure was up slightly to 9%. In per capita terms, the same source listed B.C.'s consumption as being 69.9 litres/person in 1988 and 73.5 litres/person in 1989. Using only 1989 as an illustration, had one pro-rated consumption on the basis of population, B.C.'s estimated consumption in 1989 would have been 96.12 litres/person, a difference of 24%. To be more relevant, i.e. looking at the case of Ontario, reported consumption by the C.S.D. was 106.1 litres/person in Ontario in 1989. Pro-rated consumption, however, would be 96.13 litres per person, an underestimate of 10.4%. It is not our intent to discredit the authors, but rather to point out to our readers the serious errors caused by pro-rated estimates. In effect, pro-rating consumption and using provincial price and income data is akin to asking whether Ontarios provincial data can explain changes in national consumption. A comment must also be made on the construction of the income variable used by Goddard and Tielu. In order to obtain a quarterly income figure for Ontario, which is not reported by Statistics Canada, the authors divided annual data compiled by Stats. Can. by four, on the assumption that consumers receive a fixed annual income which is evenly distributed throughout the year. This is a stark assumption, and although it may be considered by some to be valid under the circumstances, there must be alternatives to this method. For instance, some combination of wages and salaries (available monthly) could be used in conjunction with the yearly disposable income in order to obtain a proxy for personal income. Assuming equal income distribution ignores the fact that other sources of income often arise periodically, and that much of the fluctuation in income is due to individuals leaving and entering the labour force both voluntarily and involuntarily. Apart from Goddard and Tielu, the only other relevant, as well as recent study done on the demand for milk in Canada was performed by Al-Zand and Andriamanjay in 1988. While their study did not focus directly on milk, i.e. their aim was to study the 8 demand for dairy products in Canada, they do provide own price elasticities for milk, and more importantly compare their results with previous studies. These comparable estimates were primarily estimated in the mid. to late 1970's by authors such as Hassan & Johnson, Sahi & Hassan, and Sahi & Harrington. The estimates were primarily derived by ordinary least squares, and in some cases by seemingly unrelated equations. It is surprising to find that none of these studies estimated the demand for milk as a function of other beverages, but rather as a function of other dairy products and in one case (Spencer & Feaver), milk powder was used as a substitute for fluid milk. In general, these studies found the demand for milk to be relatively inelastic with estimates ranging between -0.30 and -0.47. Turning to estimates of milk demand in the United States, the literature review uncovered three recent articles which were of interest. Hein and Wessells (1988) estimated the demand for dairy products in the U.S. using cross sectional data from 1977-1978 and utilizing the Almost Ideal Demand System. The data on food consumption for households in the survey were aggregated into twelve categories, and contained prices and expenditures for over 1000 food items as well as detailed demographic information on each of the households. Their results suggest that demographic variables, such as household members, age, meals eaten away from home, etc. are highly significant. Moreover, the demand for dairy products was found to generally be inelastic, and cross-price effects were moderate. The second article of interest was that of Kinnucan (1987), who modelled the effect of Canadian Advertising on milk demand in the Buffalo, New York market. Using a single equation method, in log form, the author found the demand for milk to be much more elastic than most previous estimates. The paper, however, fails in its attempt to clearly explain the effect of Canadian Advertising on milk demand in Buffalo. Moreover, the author states that one of his objectives is to examine the effectiveness of 9 the Ontario milk marketing board commercials versus that of the American Dairy Association, but this never does materialize. Lastly, Boehm estimated the demand for milk in the United States, by region, using ordinary least squares. Ethnic composition, age distribution, prices, income, and the physical environment were all found to be statistically significant. Of interest, however, was the elasticity of milk calculated for Seattle, Washington, which was found to be approximately -.27 for the OLS estimation and -.11 for the combined cross section/time series model. 2.2 RELEVANT THEORY A fundamental premise in economic theory is that consumers are rational, and that they will select goods/services which, subject to an income constraint and predetermined prices will maximize satisfaction (or utility) from consuming these goods/services. Moreover, there is the assumption that consumers allocate a fixed amount of income across commodities which generate utility, with the demand for a particular commodity determined by a two stage budgeting process. The two step process assumes that consumers maximize a utility function which is weakly separable. In the first stage, expenditure is allocated among a broad group of goods such as food, shelter, and entertainment. At this stage, there must be an appropriate knowledge of total expenditure, as well as a defined group of prices. The second stage of the process is characterized by group expenditures being allocated among individual commodities contained within that specific group. At the second stage, individual expenditures are a function of total expenditure and prices for that group. Moreover, the result of the two stage process must be identical to what would result if the allocation was made in one step with complete information. 1 0 The voluminous literature available on demand analysis for beverages, including those already surveyed, suggests that three factors, other than price and income, significantly influence the demand for beverages: 1. The demographic make-up of society 2. The physical environment 3. The product environment Demographics Recent studies on fluid milk demand have found ethnicity, age and sex of the consuming unit to significantly explain differences in consumption. In the United States, it is widely held that the black population consumes less milk per capita than that does the white population. Now, while the black population in B.C. is not significant, there are other ethnic groups which tend to exhibit lower than average milk consumption. For example, it has been observed that the Asian population, specifically Chinese consume less milk than most British Columbians, an observation that is strengthened by the fact that milk is not a widely held commodity among storekeeper's in Vancouver's Chinatown. Unfortunately, Statistics Canada does not publish estimates of ethnic background on a frequent basis, and as such, data restrictions force us to exclude ethnicity as a variable. Apart from ethnicity or race, many studies have also found age and sex composition, as well as the number of people in a family to be important in explaining variations in milk consumption. While this analysis will use a population and age (% of population under 15) variable, we do not feel that a sex component is necessary in explaining consumption behaviour. 1 1 Physical environment It is reasonable to assume that temperature plays a major role in the consumption of beverages. Hotter days undoubtedly result in increased consumption of cold beverages, while colder winter days result in greater consumption of hot drinks. As such, a variable may be included for the mean high temperature in the province. Product environment Recent studies on milk demand have found advertising to be a significant variable in affecting milk consumption (Goddard, Kinnucan). Since the objective of advertising is to "push out" the demand curve, it is quite reasonable to find this variable to be significant. Unfortunately, these data on advertising expenditures are very expensive, and as result we are forced to exclude advertising from the analysis. 2,3 FUNCTIONAL FORM A problem faced by most applied economists is the choice of functional form for estimating systems of demand equations. The function chosen is desired to be general in nature, such that it may act as a second-order approximation to any arbitrary direct or indirect utility or cost function. Unfortunately, there are no clear rules for the choice of functional form, and as such most researchers base their decision on the popularity of models. Models which are popular in current use include the Rotterdam model (Theil and Barten), the Translog (Christensen, Jorgensen & Lau), and the Almost Ideal Demand System (Deaton & Muellbauer). Given that the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS) has recently become quite popular with Ag. Economists, as evidenced by the large number of recent journal articles in the American Journal of Ag. Economics utilizing the AIDS, we propose to estimate fluid milk demand in B.C. using the AIDS and make a comparison with the Linear Expenditure System (LES), which 1 2 we also estimate. The Linear Expenditure System has been estimated extensively in the literature. 2.3.1 THE STATIC AIDS According to Deaton and Muellbauer (1980, 312), "Our model, which we call the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS), gives an arbitrary first-order approximation to any demand system; it satisfies the axioms of choice exactly; it aggregates perfectly over consumers without invoking parallel linear Engel curves; it has a functional form which is consistent with known household-budget data; it is simple to estimate, largely avoiding the need for non-linear estimation; and it can be used to test the restrictions of homogeneity and symmetry through linear restrictions on fixed parameters. Although many of these desirable properties are possessed by one or other of the Rotterdam or translog models, neither possesses all of them simultaneously." In budget share form, the AIDS demand functions are written as, (1) wi = ai + Z-yij log pj + pi log (X/P) j where, wi = (piqiVX X =Ipiqi and P is a price index defined by, (2) log P = ao +1 aj log pj + 1/2 *ZS yij log pi log pj j j i Substitution of (2) into (1) yields (3), (3) wi = (ai - pi ao) +1 "ft log pj j + Pi{log X - 1 aj log pj - 1/2*ZI -yji log pj tog pi} j j " 1 3 Given economic theory, the basic restrictions needed for a theoretically valid model are as follows:1 n n n (4) I oi =1 i=1 l7 i j = 0 XPi -0 } adding up i=1 i=1 (5) ly i j = 0 } homogeneity (6) yij = Yji } symmetry Readers interested in a detailed exposition on the construction of (1) and (2) are asked to consult Oeaton & Muellbauer (1980). The uncompensated elasticities (r|jj) derived from (3), in general form, are, (7) T|ij = {[yij - pi(ccj + 1 Tdj log pi)] / wi} - 5ij where, 8ij is the Kronecker delta ( 8ij =1 if i=j and 6ij = 0 if i * j). The elasticities given in (7) refer to allocations within the commodity group while holding total group expenditures and all other prices constant. Derivation of rjij is given in Appendix 1. The expenditure elasticities (T|ix) derived from (3), in general form, are (8) riix= 1+(Pi/wi) and can be derived in a fashion similar to that required to find rjij. Note that those goods for which Pi < 0 , the expenditure elasticity will result in an estimate less than one, while positive pi's lead to expenditure elasticities larger than one. Thus, negative 1 Readers will notice that the imposition of symmetry makes restriction (5) redundant, for it becomes encompassed by the second term in restriction (4). 1 4 values will be ascribed to commodities which are necessities within this beverage group while positive values are ascribed to luxuries. . Since the data used in this model span only a period of three years, and given that the age composition of the population is reported annually, inclusion of an age variable in the system is clearly not practical. However, since temperatures are reported monthly, we may include a variable for the mean bi-monthly B.C. maximum temperature. The inclusion of this variable alters (1) only slightly. In fact, the only change that occurs is with respect to ai, i.e. ai is now defined as, (9) aj= aio + 5i T where, T is the bi-monthly B.C. mean high temperature. As a result, (3) is also transformed slightly to (3'), (3') wi = (aio + 5iT - pi ao) + X Yij 'og pj j + pi{log X - X aj log p] -1/2 X Z yji log pj log pi} j j ' This imposes an added restriction on aio and 5i T which, as a result, changes (4) to n n n n (41) XaiO = 1 15i = 0 I -ft = 0 I p*i = 0 } adding up i=1 i=1 i=1 i=1 We propose the use of (3') in this study, with restrictions (4'), (5), and (6) imposed. It can be shown that estimation of a system such as that presented above results in 15 (n2+5n-4)/2 parameters to be estimated, when homogeneity and symmetry are imposed: (n-1) aio's, (n-1) 5i's , (n-1) pi 's, n 2 - (1/2 * (n 2 +n)) -yfj's , 1 ao. In order to introduce dynamics into the system of equations represented by (3'), we extend the model by specifying the cti's to be functions of both temperature and a time trend. It would be ideal to introduce lagged consumption in place of a time trend, but for reasons which shall be discussed below, it would be theoretically impractical. We now define ai as, (10) aj= aio + 5i T + ei Trend where, T is temperature and Trend is a trend variable. With this change, the Dynamic Aids can be written in general form as, (11) wi = (aio + 5iT + ej Trend - pi ao) + S Yij log pj 2.3.2 THE DYNAMIC AIDS + Pi{log X - 1 aj log pj - 1 / 2 1 1 yji log pj log pi} j j i with restrictions as follows (see footnote 1), n n n n n (12) Sai0 = 1 i=1 I5i = 0 I8i = 0 X Yij = 0 X Pi = 0 } adding up i=1 i=1 i=1 (13) lYi j = 0 } homogeneity (14) yij = Yji } symmetry 16 Since the trend variable is the same for all equations, we see that the restriction £e ,=0 is entirely valid. However, had we introduced a lagged variable in place of the Trend variable, the restriction X£i=0 could only be imposed on an ad-hoc basis, since different lagged variables appear in all equations. Blanciforti, Green, and King (1986) include lags in their Almost Ideal Demand System with the restriction X£ i (lag qj)=0 . But, since different lags appear in all equations, the restriction ££ i=0 must still hold since Z(lag qj) will never equal zero. Thus, we see no way of correctly imposing the restriction X£i=0 when different values appear in different equations, and as such choose to use a trend variable in place of a lagged consumption variable. 2.3.3 THE DYNAMIC LINEAR EXPENDITURE SYSTEM The linear expenditure system (LES) can be derived from the Klein-Rubin utility function, which is of the form, (15) U(q<, qn) = S aj log(qj - bj) q j > b j , a j > 0,Iaj = 1 Maximizing this utility function subject to the budget constraint X= X Pi qj yields, after substitution, (16) qj= bj + (aj / Pi) * ( X - X Pj bj) j Multiplying through by Pi yields expenditure functions of the form, (17) piqj= pjbj + aj MX-Ipjbj) j and budget shares, (18) w i = jSLbj + aj *(1 - K p j b j /X ) ) X j 1 7 The system of equations presented above can be estimated in either expenditure or budget share form. Note that the individual with a demand function of this form can be described as purchasing subsistence quantities of good qj , in the amount of bj, and then distributing the remaining expenditure over all other goods, in the specific grouping, in fixed proportions aj. Therefore, the Engel curves are linear and have constant marginal shares aj. Note that if income varies widely over the sample period being analyzed, then linearity of the Engel curves may be overly restrictive. In this study, data only span a period of three years, in which case income (expenditure) does not vary widely within the sample, and as such linearity should not pose a major problem. Expenditure, own, and cross-price elasticities can be derived through simple differentiation, and are given in general form as, (19) Tiix=a,/Wj (20) i\\m -1 + bj * (1 - aj ) / qj (21) Tiij=- aj * (Pj bj /piqj) We introduce dynamics and the effect of temperature on this demand system by specifying that bj= bk> + 5i T + £j (lag(qj )). Note that unlike the AIDS, no adding up restrictions are required on 5i and £j, and that with temperature and dynamics included, estimation involves (4n-1) parameters:(n-1) a's, (n) b's, (n) 6's, (n) e's. 2.3.4 CURVATURE CONDITIONS Once estimated, it is important to check whether or not the model estimated is consistent with standard theory. Having imposed both homogeneity and symmetry (only in the AIDS), we are left with one important test, and that is of quasi-concavity of the utility function. Since symmetry of the Slutsky matrix has been imposed, we can 18 use the eigenvalues to evaluate negative semi-definiteness of the matrix. Since the Slutsky matrix is singular, we should find that (n-1) eigenvalues are negative and one is equal to zero. This should be true for all observations. In the event that these conditions are not satisfied, at some or all observations, we may follow Diewert and Wales (1988), which interested readers are asked to consult. 2 In the case of the LES, symmetry is automatically imposed and as such the same test as above can be employed. Alternatively, curvature conditions are also met if the estimated bj's are less than actual consumption of good i at each observation point. 2.3.5 STANDARD ERRORS FOR UNESTIMATED PARAMETERS Standard errors for those parameters not included in the estimation directly, due to homogeneity and symmetry are calculated as follows. Recall that in general, Var(X+Y) = Var X + Var Y + 2 * cov(X.Y) and that the standard error is simply the square root of the variance. Then, using a parameter from the AIDS as an example, the SE(55) for instance, is calculated as, n Var(5i) =Var(- l5j ) sincel5j = 0 i=1 i n-1 = IVar8j + 2 * I cov (8j5j) i=1 i*j =Var 81 + Var 82 + Var 83 + Var 84 +2 * (cov (8182) + cov (81 83) + cov (81 84)) +2 * (cov (8283) + cov (82,84) + cov (83,84)) 2The imposition of curvature conditions on some systems, the Translog in particular, results in a loss of the flexible functional form property. 1 9 Taking the square root of Var(85) gives us the SE(85). This procedure is general and can be applied to obtain standard errors of all other parameters not directly included in the model due to the imposition of homogeneity. Knowing that the sum of all 8's, B's, and ys sum to zero and that the sum of all ot's sum to 1, we can derive the unknown parameter estimates. Then, the familiar t-statistic can be calculated by simply dividing the parameter estimated by its associated standard error. 20 3 0 EMPIRICAL MODEL Maximum likelihood procedures were used to estimate the nonlinear, seemingly unrelated demand systems presented in section 2 above, while ordinary least squares was used for single equation estimation. In both cases, the SHAZAM program of White (1990) was utilized. 3,1 ESTIMATION QP THE AIDS/LES Estimation of the static and Dynamic AIDS models described in section 2 were carried out by imposing both homogeneity and symmetry. Note that since the data add up by construction, i.e. £ Wj=1, the adding up restrictions are automatically and costlessly satisfied. Moreover, since the data add up by construction, only (n-1) equations are independent, and thus only (n-1) equations need to be estimated. The SHAZAM program for the static AIDS used in this study can be found in Appendix 2. Note that this is only the main program, and that all variables such as the logged prices, total expenditure and budget shares need to be generated. Estimation of the Linear Expenditure System was also carried out using SHAZAM, and as in the AIDS model, only (n-1) equations are independent and thus need to be estimated. 3 3.1.1 DATA CONSTRUCTION FOR SYSTEMS ESTIMATION The data on B.C. beverage consumption were aggregated into the following five categories, where the figures in brackets represent the mean share of expenditure over the sample period: 1. Coffee (10.9) 2. Soft Drinks (23.8) 3. All fluid milk (55.4) 4. Tea (2.8) 5. Ready to serve apple and orange juice (7.05) 3Note that since the LES is not a complicated program, we choose not to include the program in an appendix. 21 The above aggregations were chosen mainly due to statistical reasons, the most important of which being that under assumptions of normality(of the error terms) actual budget shares close to zero can lead to estimated budget shares which are either zero or negative. Thus, given that orange juice represented a mean budget share of 2.25% over the sample period and apple juice representing 4.8% over the same period, it was thought prudent to aggregate both juices into one category. Categories 3 and 5 were represented by a divisia index for prices with the quantity index computed residually. Readers interested in construction of the divisia index are asked to consult the SHA2AM (1990) manual. All prices were standardized so that in the first observation all prices are equal to 1.0. As well, all quantities were converted into per capita terms. Since population is reported only quarterly, intra quarter estimates of population were obtained by simple interpolation. 3.2 SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION The single equation model postulated in this study takes the following form: Qi = f(Po , Ps . Pc . Y, D, Temp, Trend) where, o Qj is the per capita consumption of milk type i (low fat, standard, total milk) o Po is the real price of milk i o Ps are real prices of close substitutes o PQ are the real prices of close complements o Y is real income or some proxy for real income o D is a demographic variable, in this case the percentage of the population under the age of 15. o Temp is the mean high temperature. o Trend is a time trend. 22 The substitutes tested for in this study include apple juice, orange juice, soft drinks, tomato juice, and Washington State milk, while complements include coffee and tea. The linear form is chosen over all other forms such as the log-log, because elasticities are allowed to vary at each observation point. The log-log form, in particular, is restrictive for it imposes constant elasticity over the entire period of observation. This is uninteresting from a policy perspective, for it does not relay any trends in elasticities which may help to form policy. 3.2.1 DATA CONSTRUCTION-SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION All prices used are deflated by the B.C. consumer price index for all items. The proxy for income, salaries and wages, is also deflated by the B.C. CPI for ail items, and is divided by population in order to obtain a per capita figure. In order to avoid any acute consequences from rounding off errors, all variables, excluding the trend, are standardized by dividing each variable with its mean value. This is an attractive standardization technique for if the mean of the variable in interest is equal to 1, then the elasticity at the mean is simply the estimated coefficient. 3.3 DATA SOURCES Retail prices, consumption estimates, income, demographic and temperature data used in this study were purchased from the A.C. Nielsen Company of Canada, and collected from Statistics Canada, The United States Department of Agriculture, The Canadian Meteorological service, and The British Columbia Milk Board. Due to the fact that A.C. Nielsen data is reported only bi-monthly, the period of estimation for the demand system is from October 1987 to September 1990, on a bi-23 monthly basis. The single-equation system, however, focuses on the period 1979 to 1989, on a quarterly basis. All data used in this study are reported in Appendix 5.4 Systems Data Consumption data on apple juice, orange juice, coffee, tea, and soft drinks were purchased from the A.C. Nielsen Company of Canada. These data represent projected British Columbian sales of the above mentioned commodities, through an audit of scanner tapes at major grocery stores in B.C., as well as a manual audit of stores not capable of providing scanner data. The purchased data was on both a dollar and physical basis. As such, prices for these commodities were derived by dividing total dollar sales by physical volume. Regular and low fat milk consumption data were obtained from the B.C. milk board annual reports. Prices for regular and low fat milk were found in Statistics Canada's (62-010), Prices and Price Indexes. Unfortunately, these prices were reported on a quarterly basis. In order to obtain bi-monthly prices, the consumer price index for standard and low fat milk was used to obtain prices within quarters. The consumer price index was obtained from Statistics Canada's CANSIM main base. The average mean high temperature was obtained from the Canadian Meteorological Services', Annual Meteorological survey for Vancouver Airport. The mean high for the bi-monthly period was taken to be a simple average of the mean high temperature for the two months under question. The assumption made in using this variable is that the Vancouver Airport is a crude proxy for the changes in mean high temperatures in British Columbia. 4Due to the purchase agreement, access to A.C. Nielsen data is limited, and as such not reported. 24 Single-equation Data Prices Retail prices for commodities used in the single equation estimation ( homo, milk, 2% milk, coffee, tea, orange juice, soda pop, apple juice, and tomato juice) were obtained from Statistics Canada (62-010), Prices and Price Indexes and are for Vancouver. The price of whole milk in the Seattle area was obtained from the USDA, Dairy Administration Branch. Prices for low fat milk were not available at the time of estimation. The prices were converted from $US/gallon to $CN/litre, using the Bank of Canada's published exchange rates and were adjusted to reflect differences in volume between U.S. and Imperial gallons. Note that we deflate the price of Washington State whole milk by the B.C. CPI for homogenized milk after making the above mentioned conversion. This, because it is the price seen by B.C. consumers, and because in theory exchange rates are supposed to reflect differential inflation, and as such it is wrong to simply convert the real price of Washington State milk into Scan/litre. All CPI figures were obtained from Statistics Canada's CANSIM main base. Consumption estimates Consumption estimates for regular and low-fat milk were obtained from the B.C. milk board annual reports. 25 Incnme/Waaes and Salaries Personal disposable income for British Columbians is reported in Statistics Canada's (13-213), National Income Accounts, while figures for wages and salaries were obtained from Statistics Canada's CANSIM mini base. The former is reported only on an annual basis, while the latter is reported monthly. As such, wages and salaries were used as a proxy for changes in disposable income between quarters. Specifically, an income figure was constructed as follows, .4 Yj = PDIi* ( S W j / I S W j ) j=1 Population Population estimates for Canada and British Columbia were obtained from Statistics Canada's CANSIM mini base. Estimates of the population for British Columbia under the age of 15 were obtained from Statistics Canada (91-519 & 91-202). Unfortunately, estimates were available only on an annual basis, and as such it was assumed that the percentage of the population under the age of 15 did not change drastically between any quarter being analyzed in this study. Weather As in the case of systems estimation data, the average mean high temperature was obtained from the Canadian Meteorological Services', Annual Meteorological survey for Vancouver Airport. 26 3.4 DEBUGGING PROCEDURES FOR AIDS/LES ESTIMATION Once estimated, the researcher may check whether or not the model functions properly, i.e. that the program written for SHA2AM does not contain any errors/omissions. The following tests are quite general, and can be used for testing the program. 1. Since the data add up by construction, i.e. X Wj =1, the choice of which commodity group to exclude is arbitrary. As such, switching the n'th commodity in estimation should yield identical results. Differing parameter estimates indicate an error(s) in the program. 2. Satisfying (1) is crucial, and once satisfied, the researcher should inspect the gradient to ensure convergence. Convergence is guaranteed when the gradient is essentially equal to zero. In addition, restarting the system with the converged values as initial starting values should not increase the log of the likelihood function. While these measures ensure convergence, they do not ensure that convergence is global, i.e. as opposed to a local convergence. To test for global/local convergence, the model should be re-estimated with a variety of initial starting values. If these differing values converge to the same parameter values, then we have more faith in believing that global convergence may have been achieved. 3. Using converged parameter values, predict budget shares for each commodity. These should be similar to actual budget shares, but of course will not be exact due to the standard errors. Estimated quantities can then be calculated by recalling that, wj = (piqi)/X and thus qj=(X*wj)/pj 27 and where X is total expenditure, and wi is the predicted share. 4. Recall that the general form, for the AIDS, as shown by equation (1) is, (1) wi = ai + X -ft log pj + pi log (X/P) j Then, setting Pi=o and predicting budget shares implies that wi = ai + X Tij log pj j Scaling prices to equal 1 in a base year ensures that in the base year, wi =ai , and thus this can be checked by visual inspection. 5. If the symmetry condition has been imposed correctly, then the Slutsky matrix will be symmetric. Taking the eigenvalues of this symmetric matrix should yield at least one eigenvalue equal to 0 at each observation. This is a necessary condition, regardless of whether or not curvature conditions have been met. Once estimated and checked using 1-5 above, one may check/correct for serial correlation, which may be a serious problem. In their original article, Deaton and Muellbauer allude to this possibility of serial correlation when homogeneity is imposed, and this is confirmed by Rossi, Blanciforti and Green. Judging from other research done with the AIDS on aggregated commodities such as food, etc. rejection of homogeneity and symmetry is commonplace in the estimation of the AIDS, and that researchers have found that forcing these restrictions can lead to the presence of serial correlation. Reasons offered for this have been omitted variables, absence of demographic statistics, and habit persistence. As such, checks/corrections can be made using the AUTO command in SHAZAM. 28 4 0 R E S U L T S & IMPLICATIONS 4.1 R E S U L T S F R O M STATIC AIDS ESTIMATION Table 2 reports the estimated parameters of the static Almost Ideal Demand system estimated in this study. T-statistics are reported in brackets, and as one can immediately notice are, for the most part insignificant. In particular, all variables not directly estimated in the model due to homogeneity restrictions are strongly insignificant. Table 2 - Estimated parameters from the static AIDS estimation G O O D i a i 6i Pi YI1 Yi2 Yi3 TfS4 Yi5 C O F F E E -4.2473 -.00111 .08890 -.31487 -1.2491 1.5831 -.01226 -.00687 (-0.77) (-2.58) (1.47) (-0.44) (-1.18) (0.89) (-0.15) (0.04) S O F T -13.648 .00279 .28141 -1.2491 -3.8955 4.9691 -.03821 .213713 DRINKS (-1.93) (2.89) (2.20) (-1.18) (-1.84) (2.58) (-0.17) (0.37) MILK 18.559 -.00108 -.36554 1.5831 4.9691 -6.3905 .053154 -.21485 (1.68) (-1.73) (-4.23) (0.89) (2.58) (-2.10) (0.18) (-0.07) T E A -.15036 -.00048 .00373 -.01226 -.03821 .053154 .018301 -.02099 (-0.18) (-4.24) (0.25) (-0.14) (-0.17) (0.18) (2.51) (-0.08) A P P L E ; O R A N G E .48666 -.00013 -.00849 -.00687 .213713 -.21485 -.02099 .029001 JUICE (0.24) (-0.07) (-0.22) (0.04) (0.37) (-0.07) (-0.08) S U M 1.0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 The estimates of pj indicate that milk and juices are necessities within this group, while all other goods are luxuries. However, only milk and soft drinks are statistically signicant on the basis of t-values (reported in brackets). Recall that negative values of pi are ascribed to necessities, while positive values are luxuries. Judging from other t-values , a large number of the y s are not significantly different from zero; in fact, only 3 out of 15 y s have t-values larger than 2 in absolute value. Turning to the 5's, we see 2 9 that 3 out of 5 have t-values greater than 2 in absolute value, and all but 85 (juice) have anticipated signs. It is interesting to note that the two S's possessing t-values less than 2 in absolute value are 83 (milk) and 85 (juice). 53 enters the model with a negative sign indicating that increases in temperature lead to declining consumption of milk. A priori, this is a hard variable to decide on for sign expectation, and as such we cannot use introspection to judge the validity of this sign, but we do acknowledge the insignificance of its t-value. This is however, clearly not the case with 85 (juices). Intuition leads us to believe that increases in temperature invariably lead to increases in the consumption of juices, and as such we would have expected a positive sign a-priori. The insignificance of the t-value on 85 , however, reassures us of our a-priori expectation. Tests for curvature conditions were performed by calculating the eigenvalues of the Slutsky matrix at each observation. In order for the utility function to be quasi concave, (n-1) eigenvalues must be negative and one must be equal to zero. This should hold at each observation. Contrary to this, we found 12 observations at which there were 3 negative eigenvalues, one equal to zero and one positive value. Recall that n in our model is equal to 5. At each of the remaining 6 observations, we found 2 negative eigenvalues, 2 positive eigenvalues and one equal to zero. This was unsatisfactory. We then turned to checking/correcting for serial correlation, which SHAZAM does simultaneously. Unfortunately, the model, corrected for serial correlation would not converge, which is a problem not uncommon in non-linear models. Expenditure and own price elasticities (at mean values) are shown in table 3, while elasticities calculated at each observation point can be found in Appendix 3. Readers are warned to take caution when viewing these results, as they have not been corrected for serial correlation. All own price elasticities, at the mean, exhibit the necessary negative values, but there are several areas of concern. The most 30 disturbing result from Appendix 3 is that the own price elasticity of milk exhibits a positive slope at two observation points. Clearly, this is unbelievable, for it infers that milk was a Giffen good during these two periods, a concept which is discussed only in reference to the Irish potato during the famine. Table 3 - Expenditure & own price elasticities-static AIDS GOOD i/j COFFEE SOFT DRINKS MILK TEA ORANGE/ APPLE JUICE Expend, elasticity 1.97 2.52 .41 1.14 .88 COFFEE -0.32 -0.48 -0.64 0.02 -0.54 SOFT DRINKS -0.29 -1.45 -1.23 0.03 0.42 MILK 0.05 0.03 -0.42 -0.01 -0.06 TEA 0.13 0.45 -0.57 -0.31 -0.83 ORANGE/ APPLE JUICE -0.61 1.39 -0.82 -0.32 -0.53 In addition, casual observation suggests that the own price elasticity for milk in British Columbia should become more elastic over time. This, because a much cheaper (perfect) substitute is available on the other side of the border which can be crossed with relative ease. In fact, it is common knowledge that many residents living close to the U.S. border cross over to purchase cheaper gas and milk on a regular basis. In fact, some estimates have put sales of Washington State milk to B.C. residents at approximately 65,000,000 litres per year. (Shelford, 1988) This is a very large figure 31 which may be an overestimate, but nonetheless it is significant and if this number is at all accurate then logic leads us to believe that the demand for milk should become relatively elastic over time. 5 The estimates in Appendix 3 show own price elasticities for milk to be relatively stable over the period of observation, if we exclude the last three observations. If these estimates of cross border shopping are accurate then the stability of the estimated elasticites could be due to the short observation period of three years. Own price elasticities of soft drinks, tea and juices were shown to be relatively stable over time, and all exhibited the expected negative values. One area of concern, however, was the sudden change in the own price elasticity for soft drinks in two of the last three observation periods. These are the same observation points at which the own price elasticity of milk exhibited positive values. Comparing our elasticities for soft drinks with estimates from other work is interesting. Goddard and Tielu estimated own price elasticities for soft drinks at -0.82, while Hein and Wessels estimate was at -0.58. In terms of expenditure elasticities for soft drinks, Goddard and Tielu's estimate was 2.25 while Hein and Wessels estimate was at -0.58. Cross price elasticities ,at each observation, estimated for the static AIDS are presented in table 3 and Appendix 4. Appendix 4 also reports the elasticity of temperature calculated from the estimated parameters of the AIDS, and these elasticities of temperature for the first two years of the sample are graphed in figures 1 and 2. 5Other estimates, such as those done by Agriculture Canada have sales of Washington State milk to B.C. consumers at approximately 10% of B.C. consumption. Unfortunately, we are unable to obtain a copy of this report, and must rely on personal conversation with staff at Ag. Canada. 32 e I a s t i c i t y o COFFEE • TEA • MILK Figure 1 - Temperature Elasticities (Coffee, Tea, Milk) vs. Time Notice the obvious trends in the graphs. Coffee and tea seem to be highly responsive to changes in temperatures, which in a moderate temperature area such as B.C., corresponds to seasons. The period #'s on the horizontal scale represent bi-monthly periods during the year, so that 1 represents December and January, 2 represents February and March, etc.. Figure 1 indicates that coffee and tea consumption decrease steadily between June/July (4) and October/November (6), as temperatures are relatively high, and increases steadily between November and May as temperatures decrease. It is quite interesting to see that tea and coffee not only move in the same direction, but also in relatively the same proportion. Milk, on the other hand seems to be relatively stable, but we can discern a noticeable pattern, where milk consumption increases during November to May when temperatures are low and consumption decreasing between June and November when temperatures 33 are relatively high. Thus, coffee, tea and milk seem to exhibit the same patterns of consumption as temperatures change. Soft drinks, on the other hand, are much more responsive to changes in temperature, as consumption increases between June and December due to relatively high temperatures and decreases between December and June due to lower relative temperatures. Juices, as we have mentioned, go against prior expectations, increasing consumption between June and December as temperatures are relatively low, and decreasing between December and June as temperatures begin to rise. e I a s t i c i t y 1 2 3 4 o SOFT DRINKS • JUICES Figure 2 - Temperature Elasticities (Soft Drinks, Juice) vs. Time 4.2 R E S U L T S F R O M DYNAMIC AIDS/DYNAMIC LES ESTIMATION Estimated parameters from the Dynamic AIDS and Dynamic L E S estimations are presented in table 4 and 5 respectively (t-statistics in brackets), while elasticity estimates from both models, at mean values, are presented in tables 6 and 7. Notice that while most own and cross price elasticities are different in sign and in magnitude, 34 the own price elasticity for milk in both models is similar. Also note that tea, which was a luxury in the static AIDS is now a necessity in the Dynamic AIDS. Standard errors for own price elasticites, estimated in both models, are presented below. Dynamic AIDS Dynamic LES Estimated Standard Estimated Standard elasticity Error elasticity Error Coffee -0.30 0.65 -0.61 0.09 Soft Drinks -1.43 9.80 -0.68 0.13 Milk -0.33 4.94 -0.40 0.05 Tea -0.22 0.14 -0.32 0.11 Orange/ -0.45 0.60 -0.20 0.26 Apple Juice We compare our elasticity estimates for milk from the dynamic specifications, at mean values, with those from other studies in table 8. For the sake of brevity, we choose not to report the own and cross price elasticities over time for the dynamic specification of both models. Temperature elasticities calculated for both models are also similar to the static AIDS, and again due to the sake of brevity are not reported. We note however, that as in the static AIDS estimation, estimated own price elasticities for milk in the dynamic AIDS are also positive at two of the last three observations, which is disturbing. At this point, a note on substitutability/complementarity is in order. Strictly speaking, judging substitutability or complementarity on the basis of estimated Marshallian elasticities is false. Substitutability or complementarity should be based on the estimated Slutsky matrix at each observation point. For the LES, all off-diagonal elements of the Slutsky matrix are positive implying that all goods are substitutes. This is a characteristic of the LES, i.e. that it excludes Hicks-Allen complementarity. In the case of the Dynamic AIDS, coffee/tea, coffee/juices, soft 35 drinks/tea, and soft drinks/juices were found to be substitutes throughout the sample, on the basis of the estimated Slutsky matrix. On the other hand, milk/tea, milk/juices, and tea/juices were found to be complements throughout the period of study. Lastly, coffee and soft drinks were substitutes in only 6 out of the 18 observations, coffee and milk were complements in only 4 out of the 18 observations, and soft drinks and milk were substitutes in 15 out of the 18 observations. Again, we choose to be brief and do not report the estimated Slutsky matrices. As in the case of the static AIDS, tests for curvature conditions were performed by calculating the eigenvalues of the Slutsky matrix at each observation point. Fortuitously, it was found that (n-1) eigenvalues were negative and 1 eigenvalue was equal to zero for all observations in the dynamic LES. Unfortunately, tests on the Dynamic AIDS concluded that the system did not meet curvature conditions at any of the observation points, which is somewhat unsatisfactory. Moreover, while the dynamic LES was corrected for serial correlation, SHAZAM failed to converge when correcting for serial correlation in the dynamic AIDS. In order to determine whether or not serial correlation is a problem, we present plots of the residuals , from each equation in the system, versus time. These plots presented in figures 3-6, indicate definite patterns and while this is not a conclusive test, it is an indication that serial correlation does exist. Moreover, the statistical significance of the correlation coefficient in the dynamic LES strengthens our suspicion of serial correlation. 6 Thus, if serial correlation is indeed a problem, and indications are that it is, our estimated parameters from the dynamic AIDS are not efficient, but they are still consistent. The problem of inefficient estimators is readily apparent from the large standard errors on the own price elasticities reported previously. 6The Rho value (correlation coefficient) in the dynamic LES was estimated to have a value of -0.405 with a t-value of -2.71. 36 Table 4 - Estimated parameters from Dynamic AIDS estimation GOODi 5i £i PJ Yi1 Yl2 Y\3 Tl4 Yi5 COFFEE -1.1319 (-.78) -.72e-3 (-2.64) -.00141 (-4.86) .04374 (1.26) .02511 (0.24) -0.5245 (-1.14) 0.4762 (0.87) 0.0190 (1.97) .0041 (0.09) SOFT DRINKS -11.059 (-1.86) .00180 (2.75) .00351 (6.08) .3876 (3.8) -.5245 M.14) -4.354 (-2.12) 4.638 (2.37) .1073 (.88) .1332 (0.35) MILK 12.588 (1.95) -.6e-03 (-1.03) -.0015 (-2.95) -.4143 (-4.9) .4762 (.87) 4.638 (2.37) -4.824 (-2.27) -.1305 (-1.15) i i -.1597 (-0.4) TEA .29461 (1.14) -.4e-03 (-5.08) -.4e-03 (-6.02) -.0089 (-.82) .0190 (1.97) .1073 (.88) -.1305 M.15) .01941 (3.3) -.0152 (-0.5) APPLE/ ORANGE JUICE .3083 (0.33) -.8e-04 (-0.05) -.2e-03 (-0.07) -.86-02 (-0.3) .0041 (0.09) .1332 (0.35) -.1597 (-0-4) -.0152 (-0.5) -0.376 SUM 1.0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Table 5 - Estimated parameters from Dynamic LES estimation GOODi bio 6i £i ai COFFEE -1.2410 .21269 -.14246 .17790 (-1.20) (3.5) (-1.76) (6.03) SOFT DRINKS -3.7848 .73761 -.65846 .46086 (-.71) (2.81) (-6.89) (6.76) MILK 4.2822 .39112 .19374 .32906 (0.73) (2.40) (1.08) (9.8) TEA 0.52980 0.0143 -.28080 .025397 (4.48) (2.67) (-4.16) (2.83) APPLE/ 2.7498 0.0102 -.36768 .006783 ORANGE (2.32) (0.236) (-2.30) JUICE 37 Table 6 - Expenditure and own price elasticities - Dynamic AIDS GOOD i/j COFFEE SOFT DRINKS MILK TEA ORANGE/ APPLE JUICE Expend, elasticity 1.4 2.63 0.25 0.68 0.89 COFFEE -0.30 -0.41 -0.67 0.06 -0.08 SOFT DRINKS -0.32 -1.43 -0.94 -0.01 0.06 MILK -0.01 i 0.16 -0.33 -0.02 -0.06 TEA 0.31 0.33 -0.66 -0.22 -0.45 ORANGE/ APPLE JUICE -0.07 0.64 -0.82 -0.18 -0.45 Table 7 - Expenditure and own price elasticities - Dynamic LES GOOD i/j COFFEE SOFT DRINKS MILK TEA ORANGE/ APPLE JUICE Expend, elasticity 1.97 1.75 0.54 1.14 0.47 COFFEE -0.61 -0.27 -0.94 -0.04 -0.12 SOFT DRINKS -0.09 -0.68 -0.83 -0.03 -0.11 MILK -0.03 -0.07 -0.40 -0.01 -0.03 TEA -0.06 -0.15 -0.54 -0.32 -0.07 ORANGE/ APPLE JUICE -0.03 -0.06 -0.22 -0.01 -0.2 38 Table 8 - Price and Income Elasticities for milk-Comparison with Previous Studies AUTHOR PERIOD REGION OWN PRICE INCOME METHOD This study 1987-1989 B.C. -0.40 0.54 LE.S . This study 1987-1989 B.C. -0.33 0.25 AIDS (1) Perkins et. al 1957-1966 CANADA -0.28 -1.1 (2) Lu & Marshall 1966-1971 ONTARIO -0.20 0.36 CROSS X./ TIME SERIES(3) Sahi & Harrington 1958-1972 CANADA -0.32 0.83 2SLS Spencer & Feaver 1961-1974 CANADA -0.30 0.44 OLS Hassan & Sahi 1958-1972 CANADA -0.44 0.63 OLS Hassan & Johnson 1974 CANADA -0.47 -0.21 CROSS X. Stonehouse et. al 1958-1975 CANADA -0.76 0.21 (2) Kinnucan 1978-1981 BUFFALO -0.73 0.35 OLS Boehm 1966-1975 1966-1975 SEATTLE U.S. AVG. -0.27 -0.30 0.13 0.14 OLS OLS Hein & Wessells 1977-1978 U.S. -0.63 0.77 AIDS Goddard & Tielu 1971-1984 ONTARIO -0.29 0.43 TRANSLOG George & King 1955/1965 U.S. -0.35 0.37 CROSS X. Al-Zand & Andriamanjay 1968-1982 CANADA -0.21 0.49 OLS(4) 1- dynamic AIDS-uncorrected for serial correlation 2- estimate obtained from Lane & Fox-model unknown. 3- demand at the farm level; authors claim that if retail price =2*farm price then TJ=-0.40 4- partly skimmed milk 39 R E S I D U A L S - 0 . 0 0 6 6 9 1 0 1 1 TIME i i i 1 2 1 3 1 4 1 5 1 6 1 7 1 8 • EQ.1 Figure 3 - Coffee equation residuals v. Time 0 . 0 2 0 TIME © EQ.2 Figure 4 - Soft Drink equation residuals v. Time 40 R E S I D U A L S i i i i I . I I I i i i 8 9 10 11 1 2 1 3 14 15 16 17 18 TIME oEQ.3 Figure 5 - Milk equation residuals v. Time R E S I D U A L S o.oooq -0.0005. -o.ooiq -0.0015, -0.0020 I I I I I Y I I I I 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 TIME ©EQ4 Figure 6 - Tea equation residuals v. Time 41 4 3 RES1H TS FROM S1NRI E EQUATION ESTIMATION Single equation estimation data was unfortunately plagued with a high degree of multicollinearity, which resulted in insignificant variables, wrong signs, and un-believable elasticity estimates. We admit at this point that we in fact engaged in a "specification search" by estimating various functional forms, such as the log-log and log-linear forms, none of which were successful in yielding "believable"estimates. An attempt was also made at imposing homogeneity of degree zero in income and prices, on the single equation being estimated, by dividing all prices and income by income, and using these normalized prices as dependent variables, along with temperature, and population under the age of 15. Unfortunately, this too was to no avail. Since our objective is to obtain reliable elasticity estimates, and not simply prediction, multicollinearity in such a high degree poses a serious problem. As such, we do not present results from single equation estimation, but conclude that this may perhaps be the reason for no previous estimates on the demand for milk in British Columbia. The data used in this study for single equation estimation are readily available from Statistics Canada catalogues, which would be the most obvious data source for researchers wanting to estimate the demand for milk in British Columbia. Since it seems surprising that no one has ever attempted to estimate the demand for milk in British Columbia, we believe that perhaps this estimation has been attempted, but yielded insignificant and unbelievable results such as those found in this study's attempt at single equation estimation. 4 . 4 IMPLICATIONS We turn now to assessing the implications of the estimated elasticity. Recall that the general definition of the price elasticity of demand is: 42 3p q where p is the price of the product, q is the quantity consumed and (dq/dp) is the slope of the demand curve. Then, given our elasticity estimate, assuming linear demand curves for the sake of simplicity, and using mean values for p and q used in estimation, we can find (8q/3p) . The question we now ask is, what would be the elasticity of demand for milk in B.C. if the price of milk in B.C. was equal to the price of milk in Seattle. The data on milk prices suggest that Seattle milk is approximately thirty percent cheaper than the milk in B.C.. With this knowledge, and an estimated B.C. elasticity of -0.40, we calculate q to be q=q * (1 +(0.4*30)) when p =0.7 * p. We now have all three parameters needed to estimate the elasticity of demand for B.C. milk when B.C. prices equal Seattle prices. This elasticity is estimated at -0.25, which is remarkably similar to Boehm's estimate of -0.27 for Seattle. We also find that with a price differential of approximately thirty percent and an estimated elasticity of -0.4, we can assert that a thirty percent decline in B.C. milk prices would lead to an increased consumption of B.C. milk in the order of twelve percent. Readers will recall that Ag. Canada's estimate of milk purchased in Washington State by B.C. consumers was approximately ten percent of B.C. consumption, which is not far from our estimate of twelve percent. We note in passing, however, that this twelve percent increase is based on the entire B.C. population, whereas the part of the population purchasing milk in Washington State is primarily restricted to the Lower Mainland. Thus, we consider this estimate of twelve percent to be an upper bound on the amount of milk purchased in Washington State by B.C. consumers. 43 We now ask whether or not expansion in fluid milk production is profitable at the estimated elasticity of -0.40. Recall that the allocation of B.C. MSQ quota is based upon 35/65 th's of its fluid milk consumption. Thus, issuing an additional unit of fluid milk quota, in this case via a decrease in the fluid milk price, leads not only to an increase in B.C. fluid milk sales (along with a decrease in revenue) and increased production costs, but also to an increase in industrial milk sales. We proceed as follows: Let 7i = p , q f +p iq i -C(q f +oj) where, K = industry profit pf = farm price of fluid milk pj = farm price of industrial milk (assumed constant because B.C. production is a very small part of Canadian production) C = variable cost of production q f ,q' = quantity of fluid and industrial milk sold dqf 8q* dq f dqf which states that for profit maximization, the sum of the marginal revenues for fluid and industrial milk must equal the marginal cost of producing fluid and industrial milk. Then, differentiating n with respect to q f leads to, dji = p f + qf djjf + P'^ oi -dQ. (a) Now, TIN = dq * p ==>2p.*q = p_ dp q dq -nji (b) and by virtue of B.C.'s agreement in the National Milk Marketing Plan, 2q' = 2S dqf 65 (c) 44 Since fluid and industrial milk are the same good at the farm level, and are only classified on the basis of end use, the costs of production at the farm level are the same. Thus, 2C_ = C + 25_C (d) dq f 65 Substituting (b), (c), and (d) into (a) yields (e), ik = fif ( TH i +1) + p'25. - C - 25.C (e) dq f TVi 65 65 We assume C to be $0.25/litre, a figure quoted by some industry analysts, and use current values for fluid and industrial milk which are $0.59/litre and $0.41 /litre respectively. Note that we choose not to add to this last term the value of gain in the stock of MSQ quota, since the value of the increased profits from industrial milk sales will inherently become capitalized into the price of MSQ quota, and as such addition would result in "double counting". Moreover, note that we do not discount the flow presented by the last term above, since it does not alter the result. At these prices and cost figures, the resulting change in profit is negative implying that a unit increase in fluid milk quota leads to a decrease in profit. Given this result, we now ask what elasticity estimate is needed for the change in profits to equal zero, which would be the required estimate at which it would be just profitable (from the industry perspective) to increase fluid quota by one unit? Using the above mentioned prices and cost figures, we vary T\\\ , and find this "critical" elasticity to be -1.4. Note that since we use farm gate prices and costs, this is the "critical" elasticity at the farm gate. This figure is quite high, particularly when we attempt to convert it into a retail level elasticity. We do this by observing that the retail price is approximately 80% of the farm gate price, and therefore a crude method for conversion would be to multiply this elasticity of -1.4 by 1.8, implying that the "critical" elasticity at the retail level is -2.52. 45 Lastly, a note on the perceived consequences of our short data set is in order. Some may argue that our period of observation, three years, can only yield short run elasticity estimates. The argument is that with a commodity grouping containing non-perishable goods such as coffee, tea and soft drinks, the effects of storage or inventory on the part of a household could, in the long run, yield more elastic estimates for these (non-perishable) commodities, and by virtue of the adding up constraint yield different long run elasticity estimates for perishable commodities such as milk.7 It seems rational to expect that households will respond to lower prices for non-perishable commodities by purchasing more than is required for immediate consumption. With a data set containing bi-monthly data and spanning only a period of three years we would expect that these "stock adjustments" will not be picked up in the data, and thus if stocks are really a matter of common occurence, we cannot refute the argument that the elasticity estimate for milk in this study is short run. Only when more data is gathered for future estimation can this argument be validated. 7Economic theory requires that the own-price, cross-price and income(expenditure) elasticities sum to zero. 4 6 50 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 5.1 SUMMARY This study has attempted to estimate the demand for milk in British Columbia, and in particular to obtain an estimate of the elasticity of demand for milk. An Almost Ideal Demand System in both static and dynamic form, along with a dynamic Linear Expenditure System were estimated using data on apple juice, orange juice, coffee, tea, soft drinks, low fat milk and standard milk. We note that the Linear Expenditure System estimated met all theoretical restrictions, in particular quasi-concavity of the utility function at each observation point. In addition, an attempt was made at employing ordinary least squares to estimate the demand for milk in British Columbia, but failed to yield credible results. We believe that researchers who may have previously attempted to estimate the demand for milk in B.C. may have also run into this problem and abandoned their empirical investigation. This, because The A.C. Nielsen Co. is an unknown data source to many researchers, and without data from this source, researchers would be forced to resort to the Statistics Canada's data set, which in this case yielded insignificant results. An elasticity estimate for the demand for milk in B.C. has, to our knowledge, never been estimated or published, perhaps due in part to the reason mentioned above. Thus, using an alternate source of data other than Statistics Canada, this study has attempted to take the first step at estimating this parameter which is of great interest to policy analysts. Many have argued that the retail price of milk in B.C. is too high relative to other provinces and the bordering United States, and that decreasing the price can lead to significant increases in consumption which have ramifications for the Market Share Quota allocated to British Columbia. However, these assertions are only valid if there is a parameter to base the argument upon, in this case the elasticity. 47 5.2 CONCLUSIONS The results of this study are both credible and interesting. The elasticity of demand for milk in British Columbia is estimated to be between -0.33 and -0.40, which is in the order of most estimates done for Canada and the United States. Moreover, our analysis suggests that there is a likelihood that B.C. and Seattle milk consumers may lie on the same demand curve. Our analysis also suggests that twelve percent of B.C. consumption is an upper bound on the amount of milk purchased by B.C. consumers in Washington State. This estimate is in line with a study done by Agriculture Canada, who have estimated sales of Washington State milk to B.C. consumers at approximately ten percent of B.C. consumption.8 In volume terms, this is approximately thirty million litres, a figure well below Shelford's 1988 rough estimate of sixty five million litres of milk. Unfortunately, with an elasticity estimate of -0.40, significant increases in consumption cannot be achieved through decreased prices. Only with a more elastic estimate and a resulting net benefit to society, which includes both producers and consumers, can the calls for lower milk prices be justified by the dairy industry. It is easy to see why many believe the elasticity of demand for milk in B.C. to be elastic. Close proximity to the U.S. border where milk is much cheaper, and relatively high milk prices in comparison to other western provinces are some of the reasons. We end this study by offering recommendations for future research and restating that the elasticity of demand for milk in British Columbia has been estimated to be between -0.33 and -0.40.. "Because we have been unable to secure a copy of this report, details of its estimation cannot be provided. 48 5.3 RECOMMENDATIONS FOR F U T U R E R E S E A R C H In view of the developments from this study, we have many recommendations for future research, some of which are listed below. 1. The data obtained from the A.C. Nielsen Co. of Canada is probably the best, if not the only data available on beverage consumption in B.C.. Statistics Canada data is generally reported on a Canada wide basis, and as we have found, what little provincial data that is available, does not yield reliable or credible results. Given the lack of "good" available data and in view of the issue raised regarding the possible consequence of a short data set, it is critical that this data set be updated periodically in order for future research to be successful in providing long run elasticity estimates for milk in B.C.. Judging from discussions with Nielsen personnel, back data on bi-monthly consumption is available only for a period of three years, after which it is turned into annual data. 2. Data on milk prices and consumption are, unfortunately, not available from the A.C. Nielsen Co., and as such we were forced to resort to Statistics Canada Data. There are some lingering doubts about this data, in particular, the sudden drop in prices in two of the last three observation periods, which can be seen from Appendix 5, as well as from the CPI figures for milk in British Columbia (not included). Disturbed by these figures, we contacted Overwaitea, Safeway, and Dairyland who unfortunately could not provide us with necessary data on prices. It seems odd that prices of a staple commodity such as milk would not be collected or recorded by anyone other than Statistics Canada. One option that has not been tried is to contact a consumer advisory group that may have data on the prices of milk in British Columbia, which could corroborate Statistics Canada data. 3. The fact that the SHAZAM model could not converge when correcting for serial correlation in both AIDS models is still disturbing, even though we fully realized before attempting this project that these types of exercises are not always 49 deterministic. Perhaps the same model written for SHAZAM could be written for another econometrics/statistics package such as S.A.S. or the Non Linear Monitor. Non convergence could merely be due to the algorithm used by SHAZAM. 4. Since there are no other comparable estimates on the demand for milk in British Columbia, it may be a worthwhile exercise to attempt estimation with another functional form, such as the Normalized Quadratic with concavity imposed. Estimation of alternate functional forms is something not done by most researchers, which is odd in many ways, for we always hear about dilemmas on the choice of functional form. When it comes to estimating a model, most researchers simply pick a model on the basis of popularity, but then do nothing to test the robustness of their results by using alternate models. 5. Given that we now have an estimate of the elasticity of demand for milk in British Columbia, it may be a worthwhile exercise to determine the net benefit/loss to society due to an increase in the fluid milk quota, which would result from a decrease in the retail price for milk. This study would, of course, take into account the gain to consumers from lower milk prices, as well as the gain to producers from increased MSQ quota allocation and industrial milk sales, as well as the loss in fluid milk revenue by producers. 50 BIBLIOGRAPHY Agriculture Canada, Economics Branch. Consumer Demand for Major Foods in Canada. Publication no. 76/2. Ottawa: Communications unit, April 1976. Agriculture Canada, Food Markets Analysis Division. The Parameters of Consumer  Food Demand in Canada. Working paper 2/85. Ottawa: Marketing and Economics Branch, January 1985, Al-Zand, O.A. and Eric Andriamanjay. "Consumer Demand for Dairy Products in Canada. Agribusiness 4(19881:233-244. Arcus Consulting. Marketing British Columbia Milk. Vancouver: British Columbia Milk Board, July 1987. Barichello, R.R. The Economics of Canadian Dairy Industry Regulation. Technical Report E/12, Regulation Reference, Economic Council of Canada, Ottawa, 1981. Blanciforti, Laura A., Richard D. Green, and Gordon A. King. U.S. consumer behaviour over the post war period: An Almost Ideal Demand System Analysis Berkley: University of California, Giannini Foundation, 1986. Boehm, William T. . The household demand for fluid milk in the United States with  regional consumption projections through 1990. Blacksburg: Virginia Polytechnic Institute, December 1976. Christensen, L., Dale Jorgensen, and Lawrence Lau. "Transcendental Logarithmic Utility Functions" American Economic Review 65(1975V. 367-383. Dairy Farmers of Canada. Dairy Facts and Figures at a glance. Ottawa: various issues Deaton, A. and John Muellbauer. "An Almost Ideal Demand System" The American  Economic Review 70(1980):312-326. Diewert, W.E. and T.J. Wales. "Normalized Quadratic Systems of Consumer Demand functions" Journal of Business and Economic Statistics. 6(1988):303-311. George, P.S. and G.A. King. Consumer demand for food commodities in the United  States with projections for 1980. Berkley: University of California, Giannini Foundation, 1971. Goddard, E.W. and A. Tielu. The importance of including demographic variables when examining the impact of advertising fluid milk in Ontario. Guelph:University of Guelph, July 1988. Green, Richard and Julian Alston. "Elasticities in AIDS Models" American Journal of Agricultural Economics (1990):442-444. 51 Hein, D.M. and Cathy R. Wessells. "The Demand for Dairy products: Structure, Predicition and Decomposition" American Journal of Agricultural Economics 70(1988):219-228. Kinnucan, Henry. "Effect of Canadian Advertising on Milk Demand: The Case of Buffalo, New York Market." Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics. 35(1987):181-196. Lane, S.H. and Glenn C. Fox. A synopsis of Economic research on the Ontario Dairy  industry. 1950-1980. Guelph: University of Guelph, 1981. Lu, W.F. and R.G. Marshall. A Demand Analysis for Fluid Milk in Ontario. Guelph :University of Guelph, October 1973. Pollak, R.A. and T.J. Wales. "Estimation of the Linear Expenditure System" Econometrica 37(1969):611-628. Pollak, R.A., and T.J. Wales. "Estimation of Complete Demand Systems from Household Budget Data: The Linear and Quadratic Expenditure Systems." _ American Economic Review 68(1978):349-359. Shelford, Cyril M. An Overview of the British Columbia Dairy Industry. Vancouver: The B.C. Milk Board, November 1988. Spencer, Byron, and Christine H. Feaver. The Consumption of Bread and Fluid milk in Canada. Hamilton: McMaster University, July 1975. Statistics Canada. Prices and Price Indexes-Catalogue no. 62-010, quarterly. Statistics Canada. CANSIM. 52 APPENDIX 1 - DERIVATION OF PRICE ELASTICITIES FOR THE AIDS wj = ai + X yij log pj + pi log (X/P) j where, wi = (piqi)/X X = X piqi and P is a price index defined by, log P = ao + £ aj log pj + 1/2 * Z E yij log pi log pj J ' So, qj = wiX/pi ==> log qi = log wi + log X - log pi Now, nij = d log qj = d log w[ + d log X - d log pj d log pj d log pj d log pj d log pj d log wj = [yij - Pi( ai + X Yij log pi)] / wi d log Pj i d log X = 0 since X is held constant d log Pj d log Pi = Sij d log Pj Kronecker delta; = 0 if i * j = 1 if i=j ===> Tiij = {[Yij - Pi (aj + X Yij log Pi)] / wi} - Sij APPENDIX 2 - SHAZAM PROGRAM FOR A 5 GOOD AIDS SYSTEM NL 4/NCOEF=23 ouT=15 ITER=5000 piter=100 EQ W1 = ((a1 +d1 *TEMP)-(b1 *a0)) & +g11 *(LP1 -LP5)+g12*(LP2-LP5)+g13*(LP3-LP5)+g14*(LP4-LP5) & +b1 *(LTEXP-(a1 +d1 *TEMP)*LP1 -(a2+d2*TEMP)*LP2-(a3+d3*TEMP)*LP3) & +b1*(-(a4+d4*TEMP)*LP4) & +b1 *(-((1 -a1 -a2-a3-a4)+(-d1 -d2-d3-d4)*TEMP)*LP5)& -.5*b1 *g11 *(lp1 *lp1 +Ip5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5) & -.5*b1*g22*(lp2*lp2+lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5) & -.5*b1 *g33*(lp3*lp3+lp5*lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b1 *g44*(lp4*lp4+lp5*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b1 *g12*(2*lp1 *lp2+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp1*lp5-2*lp2*lp5) & -.5*b1*g13*(2 * lpnp3+2*lp5*lp5-2 * lprip5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b1 *g14*(2*lp1 *lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b1 *g23*(2*lp2*lp3+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b1 *g24*(2*lp2*lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b1*g34*(2*lp3*lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp3*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) * EQ W2=((a2+d2*TEMP)-(b2*aO)) & +g12*(LP1 -LP5)+g22*(LP2-LP5)+g23*(LP3-LP5)+g24*(LP4-LP5) & +b2*(LTEXP-(a1 +d1 *TEMP)*LP1 -(a2+d2*TEMP)*LP2-(a3+d3*TEMP)*LP3) & +b2*(-(a4+d4*TEMP)*LP4) & +b2*(-((1 -a1 -a2-a3-a4)+(-d1 -d2-d3-d4)*TEMP)*LP5)& -.5*b2*g11 *(lp1 *lp1 +Ip5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5) & -.5*b2*g22*(lp2*lp2+lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5) & -.5*b2*g33*(lp3*lp3+lp5*lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b2*g44*(lp4*lp4+lp5*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b2*g12*(2*lp1 *lp2+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5-2*lp2*lp5) & -.5*b2*g13*(2*lp1 *lp3+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b2*g14*(2*lprip4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lprip5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b2*g23*(2*lp2*lp3+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b2*g24*(2*lp2*lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b2*g34*(2*lp3*lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp3*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) * EQ W3=((a3+d3*TEMP)-(b3*aO)) & +g13*(LP1 -LP5)+g23*(LP2-LP5)+g33*(LP3-LP5)+g34*(LP4-LP5) & +b3*(LTEXP-(a1 +d1 *TEMP)*LP1 -(a2+d2*TEMP)*LP2-(a3+d3*TEMP)*LP3) & +b3*(-(a4+d4*TEMP)*LP4) & +b3*(-((1 -a1 -a2-a3-a4)+(-d1 -d2-d3-d4)*TEMP)*LP5)& -.5*b3*g11 *(lp1 *lp1 +Ip5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5) & -.5*b3*g22*(lp2*lp2+lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5) & -.5*b3*g33*(lp3*lp3+lp5*lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b3*g44*(lp4*lp4+lp5*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b3*g12*(2*lprip2+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp1*lp5-2*lp2*lp5) & -.5*b3*g13*(2*lp1 *lp3+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b3*g14*(2*lp1 *lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp1*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b3*g23*(2*lp2*lp3+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b3*g24*(2*lp2*lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & 54 -.5*b3*g34*(2*]p3*lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp3*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) EQ W4=((a4+d4*TEMP)-(b4*aO)) & +g14*(LP1 -LP5)+g24*(LP2-LP5)+g34*(LP3-LP5)+g44*(LP4-LP5) & +b4*(LTEXP-(a1 +d1 *TEMP)*LP1 -(a2+d2*TEMP)*LP2-(a3+d3*TEMP)*LP3) & +b4*(-(a4+d4*TEMP)*LP4) & +b4*(-((1 -a1 -a2-a3-a4)+(-d1 -d2-d3-d4)*TEMP)*LP5)& -.5*b4*g11 *(lp1 *lp1 +Ip5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5) & -.5*b4*g22*(lp2*lp2+lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5) & -.5*b4*g33*(lp3*lp3+Ip5*lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b4*g44*(lp4*lp4+lp5*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b4*g12*(2*lp1 *lp2+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5-2*lp2*lp5) & -.5*b4*g13*(2*lp1 *lp3+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp1 *lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b4*g14*(2*lprip4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lprip5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b4*g23*(2*lp2*lp3+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5-2*lp3*lp5) & -.5*b4*g24*(2*lp2*lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp2*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) & -.5*b4*g34*(2*lp3*lp4+2*lp5*lp5-2*lp3*lp5-2*lp4*lp5) * end 55 APPENDIX 3 - OWN PRICE / EXPENDITURE ELASTICITIES-STATIC AIDS "'UNCORRECTED FOR SERIAL CORRELATION OWN PRICE E LASTICITIES: PERIOD COFFEE SOFT DRINKS MILK TEA APPLE/ ORANGE JUICE O/N '87 -0.42 -1.29 • -0.32 -0.29 -0.51 D/J '88 -0.48 -1.20 -0.25 -0.40 -0.51 F/M '88 -0.37 -1.01 -0.13 -0.35 -0.56 A/M '88 -0.38 -1.24 -0.28 -0.31 -0.53 J/J '88 -0.40 -1.39 -0.39 -0.21 -0.51 A/S '88 -0.37 -1.26 -0.27 -0.20 -0.54 O/N '88 -0.43 -1.52 -0.47 -0.33 -0.53 D/J '89 -0.45 -1.27 -0.31 -0.41 -0.52 F/M'89 -0.39 -1.13 -0.24 -0.40 -0.52 A/M '89 -0.36 -1.04 -0.15 -0.33 -0.51 J/J '89 -0.33 -1.01 -0.09 -0.28 -0.51 A/S '89 -0.39 -1.21 -0.24 -0.27 -0.49 O/N '89 -0.48 -1.61 -0.54 -0.32 -0.49 D/J '90 -0.47 -1.36 -0.36 -0.41 -0.49 F/M '90 -0.38 -1.14 -0.23 -0.40 -0.55 A/M '90 -0.21 -0.55 0.36 -0.37 -0.58 J/J '90 -0.28 -0.91 0.05 -0.31 -0.52 A/S '90 -0.31 -1.11 -0.13 -0.23 -0.52 56 APPENDIX 3 - CONT. EXPENDITURE ELASTICITIES: PERIOD COFFEE SOFT DRINKS MILK TEA APPLE/ ORANGE JUICE O/N '87 1.81 2.24 0.36 1.14 0.87 D/J '88 1.7 2.27 0.34 1.11 0.87 F/M '88 1.80 2.28 0.35 1.13 0.89 A/M '88 1.84 2.17 0.34 1.14 0.88 J/J '88 1.86 2.07 0.33 1.16 0.87 A/S '88 1.85 2.06 0.32 1.16 0.88 O/N "88 1.85 2.25 0.36 1.13 0.88 D/J '89 1.76 2.32 0.36 1.11 0.88 F/M '89 1.80 2.41 0.38 1.11 0.88 A/M '89 1.81 2.22 0.35 1.13 0.88 J/J '89 1.84 2.11 0.33 1.14 0.87 A/S '89 1.82 2.08 • 0.32 1.14 0.87 O/N '89 1.81 2.25 0.36 1.13 0.87 D/J '90 1.76 2.33 0.36 1.11 0.87 F/M '90 1.82 2.33 0.36 1.12 0.88 A/M '90 1.83 2.06 0.29 1.12 0.89 J/J '90 1.86 2.02 0.30 1.13 0.88 A/S '90 1.88 1.99 0.30 1.15 0.88 57 APPENDIX 4 - CROSS PRICE AND TEMPERATURE ELASTICITIES FROM THE STATIC AIDS CROSS PRICE ELASTICITIES fnjj) GOOD i = COFFEE: PERIOD SOFT DRINKS MILK TEA APPLE/ ORANGE JUICE O/N '87 -0.36 -0.60 0.15E-01 -0.46 D/J '88 -0.26 -0.58 0.10E-01 -0.40 F/M '88 -0.17 -0.81 0.15E-01 -0.46 A/M '88 -0.35 -0.65 0.16E-01 -0.48 J/J '88 -0.50 -0.50 0.17E-01 -0.48 A/S '88 -0.38 -0.63 0.18E-01 -0.49 O/N '88 -0.53 -0.43 0.13E-01 -0.48 D/J '89 -0.31 -0.58 0.10E-01 -0.43 F/M '89 -0.24 -0.73 0.12E-01 -0.46 A/M '89 -0.20 -0.81 0.16E-01 -0.46 J/J '89 -0.18 -0.87 0.19E-01 -0.48 A/S '89 -0.33 -0.66 0.17E-01 -0.46 O/N "89 -0.57 -0.33 0.11E-01 -0.45 D/J '90 -0.36 -0.51 0.97E-02 -0.42 F/M '90 -0.26 -0.73 0.13E-01 -0.47 A/M '90 0.19 -1.33 0.21 E-01 -0.50 J/J '90 -0.99E-01 -1.01 0.20E-01 -0.49 A/S '90 -0.28 -0.80 0.20E-01 -0.50 58 APPENDIX 4 - CONT. GOOD i = SOFT DRINKS PERIOD COFFEE MILK TEA APPLE/ ORANGE JUICE O/N '87 -0.22 -1.10 0.26E-01 0.34 D/J '88 -0.21 -1.22 0.21 E-01 0.34 F/M '88 -0.14 -1.49 0.27E-01 0.33 A/M '88 -0.19 -1.09 0.24E-01 0.32 J/J '88 -0.22 -0.78 0.24E-01 0.30 A/S '88 -0.17 -0.94 0.25E-01 0.28 O/N '88 -0.29 -0.82 0.21E-01 0.35 D/J '89 -0.24 -1.20 0.21 E-01 0.36 F/M '89 -0.20 -1.48 0.24E-01 0.38 A/M *89 -0.14 -1.39 0.26E-01 0.33 J/J '89 -0.10 -1.32 0.27E-01 0.30 A/S '89 -0.16 -1.03 0.24E-01 0.30 O/N '89 -0.32 -0.68 0.20E-01 0.36 D/J '90 -0.27 -1.09 0.20E-01 0.37 F/M '90 -0.19 -1.37 0.23E-01 0.35 A/M '90 0.50E-01 -1.84 0.28E-01 0.25 J/J '90 -0.54E-01 -1.35 0.26E-01 0.27 A/S *90 -0.11 -1.05 0.25E-01 0.27 59 APPENDIX 4 - CONT. GOOD i = MILK PERIOD COFFEE SOFT DRINKS TEA APPLE/ ORANGE JUICE O/N '87 0.44E-01 -0.11 E-01 -0.73E-02 -0.66E-01 D/J '88 0.41 E-01 -0.61 E-01 -0.46E-02 -0.66E-01 F/M '88 0.96E-03 -0.16 -0.74E-02 -0.57E-01 A/M '88 0.34E-01 -0.29E-01 -0.73E-02 -0.64E-01 J/J '88 0.63E-01 0.80E-01 -0.85E-02 -0.71 E-01 A/S "88 0.37E-01 -0.44E-02 -0.99E-02 -0.67E-01 O/N "88 0.77E-01 0.10 -0.46E-02 -0.67E-01 D/J '89 0.45E-01 -0.29E-01 -0.39E-02 -0.64E-01 F/M'89 0.21 E-01 -0.98E-01 -0.48E-02 -0.60E-01 A/M '89 0.33E-02 -0.14 -0.78E-02 -0.62E-01 J/J '89 -0.94E-02 -0.16 -0.99E-02 -0.63E-01 A/S '89 0.30E-01 -0.39E-01 -0.86E-02 -0.69E-01 O/N '89 0.97E-01 0.16 -0.40E-02 -0.72E-01 D/J '90 0.59E-01 0.13E-01 -0.33E-02 -0.68E-01 F/M '90 0.21 E-01 -0.90E-01 -0.50E-02 -0.59E-01 A/M '90 -0.11 -0.48 -0.12E-01 -0.48E-01 J/J '90 -0.38E-01 -0.24 -0.11 E-01 -0.63E-01 A/S '90 0.42E-02 -0.93E-01 -0.11 E-01 -0.67E-01 60 APPENDIX 4 - CONT. GOOD i = TEA PERIOD COFFEE SOFT DRINKS MILK APPLE/ ORANGE JUICE O/N '87 0.14 0.47 -0.60 -0.86 D/J '88 0.12 0.40 -0.51 -0.72 F/M '88 0.13 0.46 -0.58 -0.78 A/M '88 0.14 0.46 -0.59 -0.84 J/J '88 0.14 0.50 -0.64 -0.96 A/S '88 0.16 0.53 -0.67 -0.97 O/N '88 0.12 0.42 -0.53 -0.81 D/J '89 0.11 0.40 -0.50 -0.72 F/M '89 0.12 0.41 -0.52 -0.72 A/M'89 0.14 0.47 -0.594 -0.80 J/J '89 0.15 0.51 -0.65 -0.87 A/S '89 0.14 0.49 -0.62 -0.88 O/N '89 0.12 0.41 -0.53 -0.82 D/J '90 0.11 0.39 -0.49 -0.71 F/M '90 0.12 0.41 -0.53 -0.73 A/M *90 0.15 0.50 -0.64 -0.77 J/J '90 0.15 0.51 -0.65 -0.84 A/S *90 0.16 0.53 -0.67 -0.93 61 APPENDIX 4 - CONT. GOOD i = APPLE/ORANGE JUICE PERIOD COFFEE SOFT DRINKS MILK TEA O/N '87 -0.64 1.46 -0.85 -0.33 D/J '88 -0.64 1.44 -0.84 -0.33 F/M '88 -0.58 1.28 -0.73 -0.30 A/M '88 -0.61 1.38 -0.81 -0.32 J/J '88 -0.64 1.48 -0.87 -0.33 A/S '88 -0.60 1.37 -0.80 -0.31 O/N '88 -0.61 1.42 -0.84 -0.32 D/J '89 -0.62 1.41 -0.83 -0.32 F/M '89 -0.62 1.39 -0.80 -0.32 A/M '89 -0.64 1.41 -0.81 -0.33 J/J '89 -0.65 1.42 -0.81 -0.33 A/S '89 -0.67 1.51 -0.87 -0.34 O/N '89 -0.66 1.56 -0.93 -0.35 D/J *90 -0.66 1.51 -0.89 -0.34 F/M *90 -0.59 1.33 -0.77 -0.31 A/M '90 -0.5 1.15 -0.62 -0.28 J/J '90 -0.64 1.38 -0.78 -0.32 A/S '90 -0.63 1.41 -0.81 -0.32 62 APPENDIX 4 - CONT. TEMPERATURE ELASTICITIES PERIOD COFFEE SOFT DRINKS MILK TEA APPLE/ ORANGE JUICE O/N '87 -0.13 0.16 -0.25E-01 -0.24 -0.25E-01 D/J '88 -0.57E-01 0.81 E-01 -0.13E-01 -0.98E-01 -0.12E-01 F/M '88 -0.94E-01 0.12 -0.18E-01 -0.16 -0.16E-01 A/M '88 -0.16 0.18 -0.29E-01 -0.27 -0.28E-01 J/J '88 -0.22 0.22 -0.41 E-01 -0.42 -0.40E-01 A/S '88 -0.22 0.21 -0.41 E-01 -0.42 -0.37E-01 O/N '88 -0.12 0.15 -0.22E-01 -0.20 -0.22E-01 D/J '89 -0.74E-01 0.10 -0.15E-01 -0.12 -0.15E-01 F/M '89 -0.89E-01 0.13 -0.16E-01 -0.14 -0.16E-01 A/M '89 -0.16 0.19 -0.30E-01 -0.27 -0.30E-01 J/J '89 -0.21 0.22 -0.39E-01 -0.37 -0.38E-01 A/S '89 -0.20 0.21 -0.40E-01 -0.37 -0.40E-01 O/N '89 -0.12 0.15 -0.22E-01 -0.20 -0.23E-01 D/J '90 -0.69E-01 0.96E-01 -0.14E-01 -0.11 -0.14E-01 F/M '90 -0.86E-01 0.11 -0.16E-01 -0.13 -0.15E-01 A/M '90 -0.16 0.16 -0.32E-01 -0.25 -0.25E-01 J/J '90 -0.22 0.21 -0.43E-01 -0.37 -0.39E-01 A/S '90 -0.24 0.22 -0.46E-01 -0.44 -0.41 E-01 63 APPENDIX 5 - DATA USED IN SYSTEM /SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION DATA USED IN DEMAND SYSTEM ESTIMATION: RESTRICTED ACCESS TO DATA A P P E N D I X 5 - C O N T . D A T A USED IN DEMAND SYSTEM E S T I M A T I O N : R E S T R I C T E D A C C E S S TO DATA APPENDIX 5 - CONT. DATA USED IN SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION: Soft Tea O J . Drink A.J. Std. Low Wash Coffee ($/ ($/ ($/ ($/ Tom. Milk Fat State ($/ 100 1.36 750 1.36 Juice $/lt $/lt $c/lt 369g) bags) litre) ml.) litre) $/lt 0.63 0.63 0.58 3.39 3.32 1.30 0.50 1.13 0.99 0.67 0.65 0.58 3.00 3.45 1.35 0.53 1.23 1.04 0.67 0.67 0.59 2.91 3.42 1.36 0.54 1.22 1.06 0.69 0.68 0.61 3.74 3.50 1.39 0.57 1.33 1.11 0.71 0.70 0.61 3.76 3.55 1.41 0.56 1.34 1.06 0.75 0.72 0.62 4.04 3.47 1.42 0.65 1.47 1.17 0.75 0.76 0.61 4.11 3.47 1.45 0.70 1.47 1.21 0.78 0.78 0.63 3.90 3.48 1.47 0.74 1.45 1.3 0.78 0.80 0.65 3.86 3.55 1.48 0.75 1.48 1.32 0.83 0.82 0.65 3.16 3.52 1.67 0.73 1.47 1.34 0.83 0.84 0.66 3.07 3.63 1.73 0.75 1.43 1.35 0.88 0.86 0.66 3.00 3.75 1.75 0.77 1.72 1.46 0.88 0.89 0.67 3.31 3.73 1.78 0.78 1.59 1.52 0.92 0.88 0.71 4.10 3.77 1.85 0.80 1.66 1.65 0.91 0.93 0.72 3.37 3.80 1.92 0.86 1.69 1.64 0.96 0.93 0.71 3.35 3.73 1.96 0.77 1.76 1.68 0.98 0.95 0.71 3.27 3.75 1.95 0.86 1.74 1.74 0.98 0.95 0.71 3.29 3.68 1.95 0.84 1.75 1.77 0.99 0.96 0.71 3.24 3.67 1.95 0.89 1.72 1.75 1.00 0.97 0.72 3.23 3.75 2.00 0.80 1.66 1.73 1.00 0.97 0.73 3.33 3.85 2.08 0.89 1.66 1.7 1.02 0.99 0.76 3.43 4.13 2.13 0.89 1.69 1.8 1.02 0.99 0.77 3.50 4.50 2.11 0.92 1.65 1.85 1.03 1.00 0.78 3.75 4.92 2.22 0.91 1.62 1.7 1.03 1.00 0.80 3.69 5.10 2.18 0.83 1.61 1.78 1.04 1.01 0.81 3.67 5.07 2.23 0.85 1.60 1.83 1.04 1.01 0.80 3.57 5.00 2.24 0.86 1.62 1.79 1.05 1.02 0.81 3.62 4.87 2.23 0.95 1.61 1.79 1.05 1.02 0.82 3.66 3.94 2.24 0.91 1.59 1.87 1.08 1.05 0.81 4.21 4.81 2.14 0.87 1.57 1.88 1.08 1.05 0.81 4.76 4.65 2.26 0.79 1.56 1.95 1.08 1.05 0.81 4.48 4.10 2.18 1.07 1.57 1.74 1.08 1.05 0.79 4.02 4.00 1.95 0.96 1.58 1.77 1.08 1.05 0.78 3.80 3.96 2.21 0.87 1.63 1.93 1.07 1.04 0.78 3.46 3.71 2.38 0.97 1.49 1.95 66 1.07 1.04 0.77 3.20 3.72 2.41 1.05 1.48 1.87 1.07 1.04 0.75 3.27 3.78 2.21 0.94 1.49 1.74 1.07 1.04 0.72 3.17 3.79 2.51 1.03 1.50 1.9 1.08 1.05 0.71 3.02 3.58 2.42 0.99 1.55 1.96 1.07 1.04 0.72 2.71 3.86 2.45 0.77 1.52 1.8 1.14 1.13 0.73 2.71 3.86 2.52 0.98 1.48 1.83 1.12 1.09 0.73 2.96 4.01 2.54 0.84 1.29 2.03 1.10 1.09 0.72 3.26 3.99 2.57 0.89 1.35 1.98 1.12 1.10 0.74 3.08 4.04 2.34 0.99 1.45 2.11 6 7 APPENDIX 5 -CONT. DATA USED IN SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION CPI CPI CPI CPI CPI CPI ALL HOMO. LOW CPI CPI APPLE CPI NON- CAN ITEMS MILK FAT OUH-fcb TEA JUICE OJ. ALCOK VEQ B.C. B.C. B.C. B.C. B.C. B.C. B.C. B.C. B.C. 77.80 76.30 76.10 90.40 96.20 80.20 78.70 72.30 76.10 79.40 78.30 77.90 82.60 94.90 82.80 81.20 75.00 77.10 80.90 80.70 80.30 91.10 94.80 86.80 81.80 79.00 79.80 82.10 82.30 81.90 105.50 95.30 91.40 84.10 78.20 82.10 83.70 84.30 84.00 106.60 96.10 93.50 85.40 81.60 84.20 86.20 87.50 87.30 102.00 96.30 94.50 85.70 85.50 85.00 88.70 91.30 91.20 104.80 95.60 93.50 87.40 90.60 87.30 91.40 93.70 93.70 106.40 97.00 95.90 88.60 99.60 89.70 95.20 96.40 96.40 104.50 99.30 97.00 89.30 98.70 93.20 98.60 98.60 98.50 101.50 98.40 96.90 101.00 98.70 ' 97.90 101.60 101.00 101.00 98.80 100.80 98.10 104.10 99.00 102.10 104.60 104.00 104.00 96.40 101.50 108.10 105.70 103.60 106.70 107.10 107.10 107.20 98.80 100.80 115.30 107.60 107.70 113.40 109.80 109.60 110.00 102.10 104.90 120.30 111.60 109.70 117.80 111.90 111.80 112.20 104.30 103.00 122.70 112.20 110.30 120.50 113.30 114.60 115.00 104.30 103.50 127.70 112.80 106.90 124.00 114.20 115.70 116.10 104.20 103.70 126.50 115.30 114.30 126.30 115.90 116.50 116.60 104.40 101.80 127.10 115.30 120.20 125.90 117.70 117.60 118.10 101.90 102.70 125.00 112.30 116.90 127.40 118.20 118.10 118.20 102.10 105.50 120.70 113.60 109.30 127.20 119.40 119.40 119.80 105.20 109.40 121.00 117.00 110.70 130.20 120.60 120.50 121.00 107.30 117.40 122.90 117.40 112.40 132.50 122.10 121.10 121.40 110.20 125.90 120.10 121.90 119.20 136.10 122.60 121.60 122.10 111.60 132.90 117.70 124.20 114.70 132.40 123.40 122.10 122.90 112.40 138.30 117.30 126.50 113.70 134.50 124.70 122.80 123.50 109.60 141.50 116.80 126.60 115.90 133.00 125.50 123.30 123.10 107.90 134.40 117.90 129.20 118.30 134.00 126.30 123.70 124.20 107.50 136.30 117.60 130.60 118.50 132.60 127.20 125.40 125.80 112.50 138.10 116.10 133.20 124.20 134.00 128.20 126.30 127.00 135.80 137.60 114.20 130.70 120.20 133.90 129.50 127.00 127.80 138.10 134.50 113.70 132.80 119.20 134.80 129.90 127.20 128.10 133.30 127.30 114.40 133.90 133.40 134.80 130.80 127.20 128.10 124.80 125.20 115.40 133.00 131.50 139.60 131.90 126.30 127.30 112.20 122.80 118.60 135.30 128.90 145.30 133.20 125.70 126.80 108.30 121.30 108.30 141.00 136.80 148.50 134.20 126.10 126.60 104.10 119.70 107.80 141.40 132.00 148.90 135.60 126.00 126.80 103.70 117.20 108.30 143.90 139.10 147.00 136.80 126.20 126.60 96.30 121.90 109.60 144.30 140.50 149.90 68 138.10 128.20 129.20 84.50 119.20 112.60 148.80 136.50 151.20 139.00 123.80 126.30 79.60 122.80 111.10 147.90 128.40 150.90 140.70 126.00 127.40 86.80 123.90 108.20 152.00 137.20 153.80 142.40 120.50 122.80 84.40 127.20 94.10 149.50 125.40 148.30 144.60 120.20 125.80 88.10 129.80 98.70 149.30 132.90 155.30 146.20 123.50 128.90 83.50 129.70 105.50 150.00 133.20 153.90 69 APPENDIX 5 - CONT. DATA USED IN SINGLE EQUATION ESTIMATION STANDARD LOW FAT POP. TEMP. MILK MILK POP. B.C. INCOME VAN. CONSUMP. CONSUMP. B.C. <15 YEARS (SEE §3.3) AIRPORT l/cap/qtr. l/cap/qtr. 000'S % 000's (°c) 11.52 14.13 2572.1 22.1 3883925 7.3 11.63 13.96 2581.8 22.1 4018468 16.6 12.17 14.01 2593.6 22.1 4238490 21.4 11.92 14.75 2614.8 22.1 4406162 10.4 11.39 14.55 2636.4 21.8 4552207 7.0 11.46 14.26 2654.1 21.8 4736641 16.0 11.79 14.50 2672.2 21.8 5010559 20.0 11.60 14.98 2694.2 21.8 5257799 10.6 11.09 14.61 2717.7 21.4 5379278 9.5 11.27 14.37 2733.2 21.4 5678414 15.3 11.45 14.37 2784.9 21.4 5666347 20.9 11.32 15.10 2763.2 21.4 6023885 9.9 10.66 14.83 2774.1 21.2 6050464 6.8 10.61 14.55 2781.4 21.2 5968214 16.5 10.65 14.72 2790.8 21.2 5661493 20.1 10.26 15.04 2798.2 21.2 5824550 9.4 9.95 14.99 2802.7 20.9 5925862 10.0 9.66 14.47 2808.7 20.9 5975925 16.8 9.98 14.48 2817.3 20.9 5967699 19.9 9.71 14.85 2826.9 20.9 5867864 8.9 9.28 14.99 2833.8 20.8 5867961 9.2 9.14 14.81 2840.9 20.8 6077305 15.3 9.14 14.63 2851 20.8 6139590 20.6 8.93 15.21 2858.2 20.8 6275517 8.1 8.50 15.23 2863 20.6 6341102 6.7 8.48 15.21 2867 20.6 6384926 16.0 8.62 15.27 2873.4 20.6 6558414 21.3 8.33 16.10 2879.8 20.6 6583022 6.5 8.17 15.71 2883.4 20.5 6627681 9.2 8.26 15.84 2886.4 20.5 6705731 15.8 70 8.57 16.26 2893 20.5 6660149 20.5 8.17 16.30 2902.6 20.5 6710879 10.3 7.68 16.06 2908.7 20.3 7066840 9.5 7.76 16.03 2917.1 20.3 7154866 17.2 8.00 16.15 2929.3 20.3 7299202 21.3 8.01 16.76 2945.9 20.3 7438697 10.8 7.66 16.66 2960.9 20.2 7585354 8.5 7.42 16.10 2972.7 20.2 7733184 16.5 7.54 16.43 2988.9 20.2 7858604 21.0 7.39 16.52 3009.1 20.2 8079366 10.2 7.23 16.71 3029 20.2 8286296 8.7 7.16 16.47 3044.2 20.2 8428246 17.1 7.34 16.66 3061.1 20.2 8613220 19.7 7.12 16.51 3085.3 20.2 8986540 10.2 71 

Cite

Citation Scheme:

        

Citations by CSL (citeproc-js)

Usage Statistics

Share

Embed

Customize your widget with the following options, then copy and paste the code below into the HTML of your page to embed this item in your website.
                        
                            <div id="ubcOpenCollectionsWidgetDisplay">
                            <script id="ubcOpenCollectionsWidget"
                            src="{[{embed.src}]}"
                            data-item="{[{embed.item}]}"
                            data-collection="{[{embed.collection}]}"
                            data-metadata="{[{embed.showMetadata}]}"
                            data-width="{[{embed.width}]}"
                            async >
                            </script>
                            </div>
                        
                    
IIIF logo Our image viewer uses the IIIF 2.0 standard. To load this item in other compatible viewers, use this url:
http://iiif.library.ubc.ca/presentation/dsp.831.1-0098531/manifest

Comment

Related Items