UBC Theses and Dissertations

UBC Theses Logo

UBC Theses and Dissertations

Patenting innovation : intellectual property rights in the new economy Ramage, Ian 2002

Your browser doesn't seem to have a PDF viewer, please download the PDF to view this item.

Item Metadata

Download

Media
831-ubc_2002-0217.pdf [ 6.68MB ]
Metadata
JSON: 831-1.0077445.json
JSON-LD: 831-1.0077445-ld.json
RDF/XML (Pretty): 831-1.0077445-rdf.xml
RDF/JSON: 831-1.0077445-rdf.json
Turtle: 831-1.0077445-turtle.txt
N-Triples: 831-1.0077445-rdf-ntriples.txt
Original Record: 831-1.0077445-source.json
Full Text
831-1.0077445-fulltext.txt
Citation
831-1.0077445.ris

Full Text

Patenting Innovation: Intellectual Property Rights in the New Economy by  Ian Ramage  B.A.Sc., Simon Fraser University, 1996 LL.B., University of British Columbia, 2000  A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT O F T H E REQUIREMENTS FOR T H E D E G R E E O F  MASTER OF LAWS F A C U L T Y OF G R A D U A T E STUDIES T H E UNIVERSITY OF BRITISH C O L U M B I A VANCOUVER, B . C . , CANADA  Faculty of Law  April 2002  accept this thesis as conforming to the required standard.  © Ian Ramage, 2002  In presenting this thesis in partial fulfillment of the requirements for an advanced degree at the University of British Columbia, 1 agree that the Library shall make it freely available for reference and study. I further agree that permission for extensive copying of this thesis for scholarly purposes may be granted by the head of my department or by his or her representatives.  It is understood that copying or  publication of this thesis for financial gain shall not be allowed without my written permission.  Faculty of Law The University of British Columbia Vancouver, Canada  Date  ii  Abstract  ABSTRACT In advanced industrial economies where, increasingly, intellectual assets are the principal source of value, productivity, and growth, strong intellectual property rights (IPRs)—conferred by patents, copyrights, and penalties for misappropriation of trade secrets—are an important inducement to invention and investment.  For this reason, the extension and strengthening of IPRs in the United  States and elsewhere in the past twenty-five years were appropriate and probably necessary. It may be that in some respects those processes should proceed further.  On the other hand, there is growing  friction over the assertion and exercise of some IPRs, particular patents, and claims that in some circumstances they may be discouraging research, its communication, and use.  The question arises  whether in some respects the strengthening and extension have proceeded too far. It is well known that the use of, reliance upon, and effects of patent protections vary across industries and technologies, but until recently there has been remarkably little empirical research documenting these differences. Fortunately, this is beginning to change, and the effects of some of the policy changes in the 1980s and 1990s are beginning to be investigated. Some evidence suggests that the effort to strengthen patent rights has indeed increased their importance and may have contributed to the growth of industrial R&D funding.  On the other hand, recent survey evidence indicates that  U.S. manufacturing firms in most industries rely more heavily on trade secrecy, lead time, and other technological protections to recoup their R&D investments than they do on legal mechanisms such as patents. This thesis examines the effects that a stronger, broader patent regime is having on today's industries. The main issues that emerge are those of patent quality and scope, as caused by problems with patent administration and litigation. Various solutions to these problems are then investigated, and recommendations made for future reform.  Contents  111  C O N T E N T S  ABSTRACT  ii  FIGURES  v  TABLES  vi  I.  INTRODUCTION  1  II.  STRENGTHENING & EXTENDING T H E U.S. PATENT SYSTEM  5  A.  The Patenting of Publicly-Funded Research  5  B.  The New Realm of Patentability  8  C.  The Creation of the Federal Circuit  III.  IV.  //  CONCERNING THE EFFECTS O N INNOVATION  16  A.  The Patent Surge  19  B.  The Patent Paradox  22  C. Semiconductor Patenting  24  D. Software Pa ten ting  28  E. Business Method Patenting  34  IDENTIFYING THE ISSUES  46  A.  46  Patent Theory  B. Patent Scope  52  2. EMPIRICAL STUDIES OF PATENT SCOPE  55  C. Pa ten t A dministra tion  -61  D. Patent Litigation  66  E. V.  51  1. THEORETICAL ANALYSES OF PATENT SCOPE  The Disconnect  "73  FORMULATING THE SOLUTIONS  76  A.  76  Reform To Date 1. FIRST INVENTOR DEFENSE  76  2. N E W PUBLICATION RULES  78  3. INTER PARTES REEXAMINATION  80  4. OTHER A I P A CHANGES  82  5. T H E P T O "ACTION PLAN"  B. Business Method Reform 1.  REVISITING THE BUSINESS M E T H O D EXCEPTION  '.  85  86 86  2. SHORTER TERMS  89  3. T H E BUSINESS M E T H O D PATENT IMPROVEMENT A C T  90  Contents  i  C. A dministra five Reform 1. N E W PRIOR ART DISCLOSURE SYSTEM 2.  D.  VI.  N E W FEE SHIFTING REGIME  y  94 95 • • 97  3.  OFFICIAL NOTICE  4.  JEPSON CLAIMS  102  99  5.  M O R E RESPONSIBILITIES FOR THE HEAVIEST USERS  104  Doctrinal Reform  105  1. EXPERIMENTAL USE  106  2.  FAIR USE  Ill  3.  REVERSE ENGINEERING  US  CONCLUSION  REFERENCES  120 127  Figures  v  F I G U R E S  Figure 1: U.S. Patent Activity (Domestic)  17  Figure 2: U.S. Research & Development Spending  17  Figure 3: U.S. Patent Activity (Total)  61  Tables  vi  TABLES Table 1: Effectiveness Rankings of Various Appropriability Mechanisms  23  Table 2: Internet and Business Method Patents Granted  62  Table 3: Patent Filing Rates, by Technology Field and Time Period  69  Part I.  Introduction  I.  INTRODUCTION  1  As the industrialized nations of the world forge into the twenty-first century, they are being propelled by the information-based technologies of tomorrow, not the resource-based businesses of old. For the software and telecommunications companies of the new economy, success depends far more on technical know-how than manufacturing might. Brainpower, not steam-power, now drives the wheels of economic progress. In a world where intellectual assets are fast becoming the principal source of productivity and growth, it is increasingly important to protect those assets with the rights conferred by patents, copyrights, trademarks and trade secrets. Usually by virtue of a statutory monopoly, such intellectual property rights provide penalties for the unauthorized use of proprietary ideas and inventions. Yet the real value of such rights lies not in the rightholder's power to protect against imitation or theft but in society's ability to benefit from that protection. Creative or innovative activity typically involves substantial expenditures of time, effort, and money. If artistic works or inventions are easily copied, there is a smaller prospect of profits with which to recoup those costs, and so some innovators will choose not to devote the resources required to produce them.  The protection offered by  intellectual property rights counteracts this effect, thereby increasing innovative activity and providing society with valuable inventions and works of art which might not otherwise exist. Technological progress is further enhanced by the disclosure incentives of copyright and patents. By enticing an innovator to publicly disclose his invention or discovery in exchange for the grant of exclusivity, the technical advance embodied in the invention is added to the store of public knowledge, thereby stimulating other ideas and leading to further innovation. Based on this simple model, the past twenty-five years has witnessed a dramatic expansion of the world's intellectual property systems. If the intellectual property laws create incentives for people  Part I.  2  Introduction  to invent, then stronger intellectual property protection should result in increased innovative activity and technological advance—more protection, more innovation. Nowhere was the expansion more evident than in the United States. In the midst of the most severe recession since World War II and' faced with the rapid emergence of Japanese and European competitors in the computer and semiconductors industries, U.S. policy-makers in the mid-1970s had become particularly concerned about the technological competitiveness country's economy.  and productivity of the  Seizing upon stronger intellectual property protection as a way to regain the  comparative advantages they had once enjoyed, the United States embarked on a number of initiatives aimed at significantly strengthening and extending intellectual property rights, both at home and abroad. The following chronology highlights the most important of those events: • The 1976 Copyright Act, completely overhauling copyright law to include new forms of media. • The 1980 amendments to the Copyright Act, expressly permitting copyright protection for computer programs. • The 1980 Bayh-Dole Act, enabling universities and other non-profit federal contractors to obtain exclusive rights to their inventions. • The Supreme Court's decisions  in Diamond  v. Chakrabarty,  patentability of genetically-engineered organisms, and Diamond  which established  the  v. Diehr, which opened the  door to the patenting of computer software. • The creation in 1982 of the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit (CAFC), a unified federal court with exclusive jurisdiction over patent appeals. • The Semiconductor Chip Protection Act of 1984, creating an entirely new intellectual property right for the protection of semiconductor designs. • The 1984 Hatch-Waxman Act, extending the patent terms on regulated pharmaceuticals. • The 1988 Process Patent Amendments Act, blocking the import to the United States of foreign products produced by methods infringing U.S. process patents.  3  Part I. In troduction  • The 1994 Uruguay Round Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) and various bilateral agreements,  ostensibly strengthening foreign IPR  protection and harmonizing national standards. • The Economic Espionage Act of 1996, creating new federal criminal and civil penalties for theft of trade secrets. • The Digital Millennium Copyright Act of 1998, further strengthening U.S. copyright protection. • The 1998 Federal Circuit decision in State Street Bank v. Signature Financial, upholding the patentability of business methods and processes. • The 1999 Anti-Cybersquatting Act, protecting the rights of trademark holders in cyberspace. • The Napster appeals court ruling in March 2001, denouncing the cyber-circumvention of copyright laws.  Looking back, it seems incontrovertible that the strengthening and extending of intellectual property rights has translated into greater innovation and economic growth.  The past two decades  have played host to the greatest technological advances in the history of human civilization. The current rate of technological advance is simply amazing. Research and development expenditures have never been higher. Productivity numbers are way up. Yet there is growing friction over the acquisition and assertion of intellectual property rights, especially patents. Recent litigation has highlighted the existence of patents on inventions which seem patently obvious or overly broad, particularly in the new area of business method patenting.  In the  software and semiconductor industries, the proliferation of patents appears to be erecting significant barriers to innovation. Furthermore, there is limited evidence that a stronger patent system has actually led to increased spending on research and development in the United States. Indeed, a number of surveys  Part I.  Introduction  4  have revealed that patents are considered to be among the least effective means for recouping investments in research and development. Paradoxes abound, forcing us to seriously question the traditional incentive model. It may be that patents aren't actually fostering innovation, they're hindering it—either directly, with barriers that discourage companies from innovating, or indirectly, by funneling resources away from research and development and into patent portfolio management, patent applications, litigation costs and damages. Using recent economic data, this thesis takes a hard look at the link between patents and technological innovation and whether it is, in fact, just a disconnect. Is the traditional model upon which the entire patent system has been built—a theory so patently intuitive as to remain essentially unquestioned for over 200 years—so far off the mark? And could that simple assumption, relied on for decades of patent reform in the United States and elsewhere, be doing more harm than good? In Part II: Strengthening and Extending the Patent System, I'll trace the developments in U.S. patent law over the last twenty years and identify how patent rights have been strengthened and dramatically extended. Part III: Concerning the Effects on Innovation will examine the effects that the new patent rights are having on the various industries of the new economy, including semiconductors, software, and the Internet. In Part IV: Identifying the Issues, I will review the theory behind the patent system and its recent expansion and fortification, and then lay out the main issues, including patent scope, patent administration and patent litigation. Part V : Formulating the Solutions will survey the proposed reforms. What can be done to make the patent system work better? What has been done so far to address the problems? How can we reconnect the patent system with innovation?  Part II.  II.  Strengthening  & Extending  5  the U.S. Patent System  S T R E N G T H E N I N G  & E X T E N D I N G T H E U . S . P A T E N T  Nineteen-eighty was a watershed year for the United States patent system.  SYSTEM  A series of legislative  initiatives extended patent protection to a whole new set of players—universities and federally-funded laboratories. Then, in two landmark decisions, the Supreme Court extended the reach of the patent system into two entirely new areas of endeavour—biotechnology and software.  Two years later, the  creation of a new patent court—the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit—resulted in a significant reinforcement of those rights and their further expansion beyond the traditional frontiers of patentable subject matter.  A.  The Patenting ofPublicly-Funded Research  Traditionally, U.S. law regarding the patentability of federally-funded research provided that the government held title to any invention generated with its funds. As patent holder, it could then issue royalty-free non-exclusive technology.  licenses to any private manufacturers wishing to commercialize the  Post-war efforts to allow federal contractors and universities to assume title to their  inventions were met with opposition by those arguing that the results of federally-funded research should inure to the benefit of the public, not a private monopoly under which the public is charged for the use of a technology it had funded. This debate continued through the 1950s, and, despite being the topic of over four special commissions and forty congressional hearings or reports, in 1979 there was still no comprehensive policy regarding the patenting of publicly-funded research in place.  1  A few universities patented fairly  actively, but their patents represented either the fruits of research performed with no federal funding,  1  Adam B. Jaffe, "The U.S. Patent System in Transition: Policy Innovation and the Innovative Process" (1999) National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W7280 at S n.3.  Part II. Strengthening  & Extending  6  the U.S. Patent System  patents sought for public or professional prestige and not commercial development, or inventions that had received a title rights waiver from the federal agency funding the research.  Some agencies  routinely granted such waivers, a few others signed blanket agreements that permitted certain universities to patent the results of all research funded by that agency, but the majority of agencies kept full title and offered only non-exclusive licenses. By the late 1970s, it was obvious that such a system was almost completely ineffective at commercializing federal research. Private firms had little incentive to spend resources on developing federal research into marketable products if that research remained in the public domain for anyone else to develop as well.  2  Quite rightly, businesses viewed the government's non-exclusive licenses as  "no patent protection at all," and stayed away in droves—of the 28,000 patents owned by the government at the time, a mere four percent had been licensed to private industry for further development.  3  Faced with additional evidence that the failure to patent federally-financed discoveries  had allowed foreign competitors to expropriate them instead, Congress began to pass various pieces of legislation that eventually allowed all publicly-funded research to be either patented or exclusively licensed. The most important of these was the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980, which allowed universities and 4  other non-profit institutions to automatically retain title to patents derived from federal research,  2  A firm c o u l d be assured o f profiting f r o m its expenditures only i f it could secure a competitive advantage—that is, only i f it c o u l d , through exclusive licensing o f the patented invention, appropriate the discovery for itself.  3  See A r t i K . R a i , "Regulating Scientific Research: Intellectual P r o p e r t y Rights and the N o r m s o f Science" (1999) 94 N w . U . L . R e v . 7 7 a t 9 7 n . l l 3 — q u o t i n g statement from S. R e p . N o . 96-480 at 28 (1979). T h e extension o f patent protection to federally-funded inventions, then, was deemed necessary "not for the traditional reason that such rights w o u l d provide an incentive to invent, but rather as an incentive for private firms to undertake the further investment necessary to translate the inventions into marketable products." Rai at 9 6 .  4  P u b . L . N o . 9 6 - 5 1 7 , 6(a), 94 Stat. 3 0 1 5 , 3019-28 (1980), codified as amended at 35 U . S . C . §§ 200-212 (1994). In response to pressure from industry, the B a y h - D o l e A c t , originally k n o w n as the University and Small Business Patent Procedures A c t , also gave small businesses the right to seek patents o n the results o f their federally-funded research. In 1983, the right to retain patent ownership o f federally-sponsored research was extended to large businesses as w e l l . See Rebecca S. Eisenberg, " A Technology Policy Perspective o n the N I H Gene Patenting C o n t r o v e r s y " (1994) 55 U . Pitt. L . R e v . 633 at 6 3 7 .  Part II. Strengthening  & Extending  7  the U. S. Patent System  thereby removing the need to get an explicit waiver from the funding agency. The legislation explicitly recognized that technology transfer to the private sector was a desirable outcome of publicly-funded research, and endorsed the principle that exclusive licensing of such research was sometimes necessary to achieve that objective.  5  To further stimulate innovation, the Bayh-Dole Act also required that  universities share patent royalties with individual inventors, thus giving both parties an incentive to be on the lookout for patentable inventions.  6  In addition to opening up university patenting, the Bayh-Dole Act also allowed governmentoperated laboratories such as the National Institute of Heath to grant exclusive licenses on governmentowned patents.  The simultaneous passage of the Stevenson-Wydler Technology Innovation Act of  1980, made technology transfer a mission of all federal laboratories and created a variety of 7  institutional structures and regulations to facilitate it.  Over the course of the 1980s, a series of  initiatives further expanded the possibilities for patenting by these labs,  8  while a variety of  implementing memoranda and legislative clarifications extended many of these provisions to those facilities owned by the government but operated by research contractors, including the National Laboratories of Los Alamos, Oak Ridge, Lawrence Livermore, and others. The wave of legislation did not completely resolve the debate over how much ownership of government-funded R&D ought to be transferred to private sector entities—in recent years, the controversy has impinged on the patenting activities of federal labs and raised questions about the  5  T h e stated policy objective o f the Bayh-Dole A c t was "to use the patent system to p r o m o t e the utilization o f inventions arising f r o m federally supported research o r development." 35 U . S . C . § 200 (1994).  6  See 35 U . S . C . § 202(c)(7)(b) (1994). Four years later, the passage o f the Patent L a w A m e n d m e n t s A c t further expanded the rights o f universities by r e m o v i n g certain restrictions contained i n Bayh-Dole regarding the kinds of inventions universities c o u l d o w n and the freedom w i t h w h i c h they c o u l d assign their property rights to other parties. Patent L a w A m e n d m e n t s A c t o f 1984, P u b . L . N o . 9 8 - 6 2 0 , codified at 17 U . S . C . § 9 0 7 (1994).  7  8  P u b . L . N o . 9 6 - 4 8 0 , 94 Stat. 2311 (1980), codified at 15 U . S . C . § 3701 (1980). See, e.g., the Federal Technology Transfer A c t o f 1 9 8 6 — P u b . L . N o . 9 9 - 5 0 2 , 100 Stat. 1785-87 (1986), codified as amended at IS U . S . C . § 3 7 1 0 a ( l ) , (b)(2)-(3) ( 1 9 9 4 ) — w h i c h later amended the Stevenson-Wydler A c t to authorize government-operated laboratories to enter into cooperative R & D agreements w i t h industry and to agree in advance to assign patents o n inventions made by federal employees to the collaborating f i r m .  Part II. Strengthening & Extending  the U. S. Patent  8  System  desirability of at least some forms of university patenting.  Nevertheless, the 1980s witnessed an  extraordinary transformation of the U.S. patent system from one in which the patenting of publiclyfunded research was the exception to one in which it is the norm.  B.  9  The New Realm ofPatentability  Concurrent with these changes in who could patent were momentous changes in what could be patented.  10  In the landmark 1980 case of Diamond v. Chakrabarty, the Supreme Court was asked to  decide whether a living bacterium designed to degrade crude oil was patentable subject matter." The Court ruled in the affirmative, establishing for the first time the patentability of genetically-engineered organisms, and by extension, biotechnology and genomics.  For purposes of patentable subject-matter  determination, said the Court, the relevant distinction is not between living and non-living materials, but rather "between products of nature, whether living or not, and human-made inventions."  12  Less than four months later, the Court heard Diamond  v. Diehr,  a case involving the  patentability of a process for curing synthetic rubber using a well-known mathematical algorithm and a  9  The extension of patenting and licensing privileges to inventors in universities and government laboratories can be viewed as an extension of the larger trend toward corporatization of research in general. See Catherine L. Fisk, "Removing the 'Fuel oflnterest' from the 'Fire of Genius': Law and the Employee-Inventor, 1830-1930" (1998) 65 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1127; Robert P. Merges, "The Law and Economics of Employee Inventions" (1999) 13 Harv. J. Law & Tech. 1.  10  In order to be eligible for U.S. patent protection, an invention must fit into one of the four categories specified by section 101 of the Patent Act, namely, "process, machine, manufacture, or composition of matter." 35 U.S.C. § 101 (1994). See Kewanee Oil Co. v. Bicron Corp., 416 U.S. 470 at 483 (1974): "[N]o patent is available for a discovery, however useful, novel and nonobvious, unless it falls within one of the express categories of patentable subject matter of 35 U.S.C. § 101." As we'll see, the new technologies of the 1980s and 90s would seriously test these traditional boundaries.  " 12  Diamond  v. Chakrabarty,  447 U.S. 303 (1980).  Id. at 313. The decision led inevitably to the patenting of the Harvard Mouse on 12 April 1988. See Carrie F. Walter, "Beyond the Harvard Mouse: Current Patent Practice and the Necessity of Clear Guidelines in Biotechnology Patent Law" (1998) 73 Ind. L.J. 1025 at 1036-37; Michael D. Davis, "The Patenting of Products of Nature" (1995) 21 Rutgers Computer & Tech. L.J. 293.  Part II. Strengthening  & Extending  the U.S. Patent  9  System  computer for the calculation of the appropriate cure time.'  3  An attempt to patent a similar  computerized process in 1978's Parker v. Flook was rejected because it violated the "mathematical algorithm" exception,' yet the Court upheld the patent in Diehr, relying on the fact that the program 4  acted in cooperation with an "otherwise statutory" industrial process (the curing).  This distinction  resulted in some rather inventive patent drafting, but the door was now open to the patenting of computer software.  15  While neither Chakrabarty nor Diehr actually involved traditional research, both decisions were likely motivated by the new Congressional mandate to better exploit the fruits of basic research.  16  In Chakrabarty, the Court looked to the committee reports accompanying the 1952 Patent Act to conclude that "Congress intends statutory subject matter to 'include anything under the sun that is made by man."'  17  In Diehr, the Court reiterated that bold statement, and by allowing a patent on a  process based almost exclusively on a mathematical algorithm, suggested that it would permit patenting of all inventions that moved even slightly in the direction of applied work.  13  14  Diamond  18  v. Diehr, 450 U.S. 175 (1981).  Parker v. Flook, 437 U.S. 584 (1978). Throughout the 1960s and 70s, computer software had been deemed unpatentable on the basis that it was really just a concatenation of mathematical algorithms or mental steps. See Gottschalk  v. Benson, 409 U.S. 63 at 67 (1972): "Phenomena of nature, though just discovered, mental  processes, and abstract intellectual concepts are not patentable, as they are the basic tools of scientific and technological work." This was based on longstanding judicial doctrine. Sec Rubber-Tip  Pencil Co. v. Howard,  87 U.S. (20 Wall.) 498 at 507 (1874) ("An idea of itself is not patentable..."); O'Reilly  v. Morse, 56 U.S. (15 How.)  62 at 116 (1854) ("[T]he discovery of a principle in natural philosophy or physical science, is not patentable."); Le Roy v. Tatham, 55 U.S. (14 How.) 156 at 175 (1852) ("A principle, in the abstract, is a fundamental truth; an original cause; a motive; these cannot be patented, as no one can claim in either of them an exclusive right."). 15  The legal strategy employed after Diehr might be called the "Doctrine of the Magic Words"—software was now patentable subject matter, but only if you spoke the magic words and pretended you were patenting something else entirely. In the 1980 and early 90s, patent attorneys did just that, claiming software inventions as various hardware devices or machines—or even as pizza ovens. See Julie E. Cohen & Mark A. Lemley, "Patent Scope and Innovation in the Software Industry" (2001) 89 Calif. L. Rev. 1 at 9.  16  17  As expressed by the Bayh-Dole and Stevenson-Wydler Technology Innovation Acts, supra. Chakrabarty, 447 U.S. at 309—quoting S. Rep. No. 1979, 82d Cong., 2d Sess. at 5 (1952); H.R. Rep. No. 1923, 82d Cong., 2d Sess. at 6 (1952).  18  This softened considerably the requirement of practical utility laid down in the 1966 Supreme Court decision of Brenner  v. Manson,  383 U.S. 519 (1966).  10  Part II. Strengthening & Extending the U.S. Patent System  If the Supreme Court had unlocked the doors to biotechnology and software patenting, its successor kicked them wide open.  In 1994, the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit essentially  eliminated the "otherwise statutory process or apparatus" requirement from Diehr, and established that a mathematical algorithm becomes patentable subject matter merely by virtue of its being programmed into a "general purpose" computer.  19  Then, in 1998's State Street Bank & Trust Co. v. Signature  Financial Group, Inc., the Federal Circuit effectively ended what was left of the software debate, requiring only that the "practical application of a mathematical algorithm, formula, or calculation" produce a "useful, concrete, and tangible result."  20  And it opened another door—the patenting of  methods of doing business.  21  It's been a similar story for biotechnology.  Although the Federal Circuit has retained the idea  that "products of nature" per se are not patentable, it has routinely upheld patents on purified and isolated forms of molecules that occur in nature, including full gene sequences whose physiological function (i.e., the protein for which they code) has been identified.  22  Today, genes and gene fragments  are routinely patented by genomics companies such as Human Genome Systems, Inc. and Incyte Genomics, Inc.  19  2 0  23  InreAIappat, 33 F . 3 d 1526 (Fed. C i r . 1994) en banc. State Street Bank & Trust Co. v. Signature Financial Group, Inc., 149 F . 3 d 1368 at 1373 ( F e d . C i r . 1998), cert, denied, 119 S . C t . 851 (1999). The Federal C i r c u i t c o n f i r m e d its r u l i n g the next year i n AT&T Corp. v. Excel Communications,  1998 U . S . Dist. Lexis 5346 ( C o v . A . 9 6 - 4 3 4 - S L R ) ( D . D e l . 27 M a r c h 1998), r e v ' d , 172 F . 3 d  1352 ( F e d . C i r . 1999): "It is n o w clear that computer-based p r o g r a m m i n g constitutes patentable subject matter so long as the basic requirements o f [novelty and utility] are m e t . " 2 1  Business m e t h o d patents w i l l be discussed i n m o r e detail i n Section III.E, infra.  2 2  See, e.g., Genentech, Inc. v. Chiron Corp., 112 F . 3 d 495 ( F e d . C i r . 1997).  2 3  T h e patenting o f gene fragments, k n o w n as expressed sequence tags (ESTs), has been controversial because, unlike full-length sequences, their functions are typically u n k n o w n . M a n y o f these E S T patent claims are also notable for their broad scope—the applications claim not only the E S T but also the full gene o f w h i c h it is a part, as w e l l as future uses o f the gene. See R a i , supra note 3, at 103-04. A g a i n , a detailed examination o f the issues i n biotechnology patenting is outside the scope o f this paper (and m y l i m i t e d scientific proficiency).  Part II. Strengthening  C.  & Extending  11  the LI. S. Patent System  The Creation of the Federal Circuit  In the late 1970s, the U.S. patent system was widely perceived to be weak and ineffective, or at best, too slow. The Patent and Trademark Office (PTO) was so overworked that for a while in 1979, they stopped granting patents altogether.  24  Distrustful of monopoly power in general, the Justice  Department and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) took a rather dim view of patents, often colouring attempts to enforce them with shades of anti-trust.  25  The judiciary was even less kind. The U.S. Supreme Court had been hostile to patents since the Great Depression—between 1931 and 1976, it had invalidated the patent at issue in fifty-one, or 84%, of the 61 patent cases argued before it. 26 Although the majority of lower courts were somewhat more receptive to patent holders, some were worse—during the same period, the Eighth Circuit invalidated 89% of the patents coming its way. 27 Such discrepancies had led to the further problem of "forum shopping"—the practice whereby patent holders would try to bring cases in court circuits sympathetic to patents, while alleged infringers would seek out jurisdictions believed to be hostile.  This further increased the costs and delays  associated with patent cases, and acted to undermine the uniformity of the federal patent laws.  28  Adam B. Jaffe, "The U.S. Patent System in Transition: Policy Innovation and the Innovative Process" (1999) National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W7280 at 3. The Department of Justice had a special section of its Antitrust Division devoted to anti-patent advocacy and litigation, and to some it appeared that the antitrust noose would constantly be tightened. See Easterbrook, "Is There a Ratchet in Antitrust Law?" (1982) 60 Tex. L. Rev. 70S. The FTC, not to be outdone, attacked Xerox for building a great company through the judicious use of patents. See Xerox Corp.,  86 F.T.C. 364(1975).  Lawrence Baum, "The Federal Circuits and Patent Validity: An Analysis of the Record" (1974) 56 J. Pat. & Trademark Off. Soc'y 758 at 777. Id. at 762.  See Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss, "The Federal Circuit: A Case Study in Specialized Courts" (1989) 64 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1. See also H.R. Rep. No. 97-312 at 20-21 (1981) (noting that "some circuit courts are regarded as'propatent' and others 'anti-patent' and [that] much time and money is expended 'shopping' for a favorable venue."); S. Rep. No. 97-275 at 5 (1981) (indicating that Congress wanted to "increase doctrinal stability in the field of patent law.")  Part II. Strengthening & Extending the U. S. Patent System  12  In 1980, the patent system started to get stronger. Shortly after the Chakrabarty decision, the Supreme Court ruled that since monopoly power was indeed the purpose of the patent grant, efforts to extract the monopoly rents generated by them were not violations of anti-trust law. of Justice removed itself from the business of patent bashing. directed at strengthening and streamlining the Patent Office,  31  30  29  The Department  Congress enacted a series of laws  and then, with the passage of Federal  Courts Improvements Act of 1982, created a new federal patent court—the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit (CAFC)—replacing the regional appeals courts as the court of exclusive jurisdiction for all patent appeals.  32  Although ostensibly a procedural reform—it was expected that the Federal Circuit would not only solve the problem of forum shopping, but also bring a degree of specialization and in-depth knowledge to a complicated area of law, and contribute to more uniform decisions by the various district courts—the creation of the Federal Circuit had a rapid and profound impact on U.S. patent law. In only a few short years, the doctrine laid down by nearly 150 years of Supreme Court decisions was reconsidered, revised, and re-written.  29  3 0  33  Dawson Chem. Co. v. Rohm & Haas Co., 448 U.S. 176 at 201-02 (1980). See United States v. Studiengesellschaft Kohle, 670 F.2d 1122 (D.C. Cir. 1981); Lipsky, "Current Antitrust Division Views on Patent Licensing Practices" (1981) SO Antitrust L.J. SIS.  31  Act of Dec. 12, 1980, Pub. L. No. 96-S17, 94 Stat. 301S, codified as amended at 3S U.S.C. §§ 301-307 (1982). The bill increased funding to the PTO and gave the agency the power to reexamine patents.  32  Federal Courts Improvement Act of 1982, Pub. L. No. 97-164, 96 Stat. 2S (1982), codified at 3S U.S.C. §§ 14146 (1988). Technically, the CAFC was created by merging the Court of Customs and Patent Appeals (CCPA) and the Court of Claims, and is the successor to the CCPA in hearing appeals from the PTO's Board of Patent Appeals and Interferences. See Martin J. Adelman, "The New World of Patents Created by the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit" (1987) 20 U. Mich. J.L. Ref. 979 at 982-83.  33  Though, technically, the Supreme Court retained a certiorari authority to hear an appeal from the Federal Circuit, it rarely does. See Mark D. Janis, "Patent Law in the Age of the Invisible Supreme Court" [2001] U. 111. L. Rev. 387 at 387: " The Supreme Court has rendered itself well nigh invisible in modern substantive patent law. The Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit, created in 1982, has become the de facto supreme court of patents. In those rare patent cases when the real Supreme Court has materialized, the Court has left behind a largely uninspiring jurisprudence."  Part II. Strengthening & Extending the U.S. Patent System  13  The most significant of the Federal Circuit's changes was the dramatic lowering of patentability standards—particularly the "nonobviousness" requirement of section 103.  34  Indeed, the standards  came down so swiftly and so significantly that a "patentability gap" was created, as companies scrambled to obtain patents for research considered unpatentable a few years before. reinforcement of the presumption of validity itself,  36  35  Coupled with a  the result was no less than a new "pro-patent"  37  era. The numbers tell the story.  During the first three years of its existence, the Federal Circuit  invalidated only forty-four percent of the patents it adjudicated, nearly half the Supreme Court rate of 38  83%, and far less than the old appeals court rate of approximately 70%.  39  Before 1980, a district court  In pertinent part, section 103 requires that "[a] patent may not be obtained . . . if the differences between the subject matter sought to be patented and the prior art are such that the subject matter as a whole would have been obvious at the time the invention was made to a person having ordinary skill in the art." 35 U.S.C. § 103(a) (1994). Essentially, "prior art" is a measurement of the current state of technological advance. See infra, note 79, and accompanying text. The reduction of the nonobviousness standard was accomplished primarily by elevating the importance of secondary factors such as commercial success and long-felt need "to a central place in the law of patentability." Robert P. Merges, "Commercial Success and Patent Standards: Perspectives on Innovation" (1988) 76 Calif. L. Rev. 803 at 834. See Quillen, Cecil D., Jr. "Innovation and the United States Patent System Today," Presentation to the Continuing Legal Education Institute, Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Practice and Policy Issues for the 1990's (19 October 1992) at 1. Section 282 of the U.S. Patent Act says that a patent challenged in court should be presumed valid. 35 U.S.C. § 282 (1994). Prior to 1982, a party could overcome this presumption with a mere preponderance of the evidence, but in Connell v. Sears, 722 F.2d at 1549 (1983), the Federal Circuit ruled that "clear and convincing evidence" of invalidity must be put forth by the patent challenger before the court finds the PTO's decision of validity erroneous. The emergence of the Federal Circuit was not only the most influential patent policy development of the past twenty years, it was the most important ever. See Robert P. Merges, "One Hundred Years of Solicitude: Intellectual Property Law, 1900-2000" (2000) 88 Calif. L. Rev. 2187 at 2215: "Patent law, no less than copyright and trademark, has had to adapt to several major waves of innovation this century. These innovations have produced monumental changes in the fabric of the law. ... [T]he three I consider most important: (1) the 'corporatization' of patent law, following similar trends in industrial research and development (R&D) in the early years of the century; (2) the consolidation of eighty years' worth of doctrinal adjustment in the Patent Act of 1952; and—most significant of all, in many ways—(3) the creation of the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit in 1982." Merges, supra note 34, at 822, with data derived from D.R. Dunner, "The United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit—Its First Three Years" (1985) 13 AIPLA Q.J. 185 at 187-88 (Tables 1-3); reconfirmed by D.R. Dunner, et a l , "Statistical Look at the Federal Circuit's Patent Decisions, 1982-1994" (1995) 5 Fed. Cir. Bar J. 151. Baum, supra note 26, at 760. From 1935 to 1974, the validity rate for the federal appeals courts (including the CCPA) was approximately 30%. Id.  Part II. Strengthening & Extending the U.S. Patent System  ruling of patent validity was upheld on appeal approximately 62% of the time.  14  Between 1982 and  1990, however, the Federal Circuit upheld 90% of such cases; conversely, where pre-CAFC appeals courts had overturned only 12% of district court findings of patent invalidity, the Federal Circuit reversed over half.  41  A more recent study from 1998 estimated that the overall probability a patent might eventually be invalidated now stands at 54%. around 70%.  43  42  Ten years earlier, expectations of patent invalidations hovered at  Perhaps more importantly, patent lawyers now believe the court favors patentees, and  presumably, advise their clients accordingly. Thus, the new pro-patent sentiment of the courts was communicated to the potential applicants to the patent system—the high-tech companies of the late 1980s. The Federal Circuit strengthened patents in a couple of other important ways. Not only is it far more likely to have a the validity of a patent hold up in court, the Federal Circuit has also made the consequences of infringing a U.S. patent much more serious. It is now far easier for a patent holder to obtain a preliminary injunction halting the sale of the alleged infringing product, and, if successful, to win damages that far exceed those awarded prior to 1982. The Polaroid v. Kodak battle of the early 1980s is often singled out as exemplifying this trend. After claiming an astronomical $12 billion for Kodak's infringement of its instant photography patents, Polaroid managed to win a judgment for the still-stratospheric sum of $837 million, including $233 million in lost profits, $204 million in royalties, and another $436 million in interest.  4 0  44  Other  Coolley, "The Status of Obviousness and How to Assert It as a Defense" (1994) 76 J. Pat. & Trademark Off. Soc'y 625.  41  Id.  4 2  John Allison & Mark Lemley, "Empirical Evidence on the Validity of Litigated Patents" (1998) 26 AIPLA Q.J. 185.  4 3  See Cecil B. Quillen, "Innovation and the United States Patent System Today," Presentation to the Continuing Legal Education Institute, Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Practice and Policy Issues for the 1990's(\9 October 1992).  4 4  Kodak was also permanently banned from competing in the instant-camera business. Polaroid Corp. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 16U.S.P.Q.2d (BNA) 1481 ( D . C Mass. 1990), corrected at 17 U.S.P.Q.2d (BNA) 1711 ( D . C Mass.  Part II. Strengthening  & Extending  the U. S. Patent  System  15  enormous awards include $1.2 billion from Honeywell to Litton for ring laser gyroscopes, over $1 billion thus far to the Lemelson Trust for bar coding, $212 million from Steelcase to Hayworth for movable office panels, and $171 million from Mobil to Exxon for a plastic catalyst.  45  1991). That judgment was appealed, and the 15-year fight was eventually settled for $925 million. See "Kodak Settles with Polaroid" N. Y. Times (16 July 1991) at D8. See F.M. Schcrer, Presentation to the National Academies' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), Intellectual  Property Rights: How Far Should They Be Extended? (l-i  See also Gary Forger, "Common sense patents" Modern  February 2000: Washington, DC).  Materials Handling (1 May 2000) at 7.  Part III. Concerning  III.  16  the Effects on Innovation  C O N C E R N I N G T H E EFFECTS O N INNOVATION  The growth of the United States patent system has been meteoric.  Once a fragile right, valuable to  few and enforced by even fewer, the patent now stands colossal, dominating entirely new areas of scientific endeavour, directing previously non-proprietary research settings and demanding adherence by formerly hostile regions of the world. Meanwhile, major modifications to U.S. patent doctrine have made patents more valid, and more valuable, than ever. But have these changes been beneficial? What effect has this expansion and fortification had on technological innovation, the raison d'etre of the patent system? Has all this patent reform actually encouraged more innovative activity, as predicted by the traditional incentive theory? At first glance, it seems the answer is yes. As shown in Figure 1, on the next page, the number of patents has exploded over the last twenty years. More or less constant at 40 to SO thousand per year for most of the century, and actually declining through the 1970s, utility patents granted to American inventors totaled over 85,000 in the year 2000, more than double the number issued in any year from 1979 to 1986.  46  Applications, meanwhile, rose to nearly triple what they were in 1984, and seem to  be on a lunar trajectory. Research and development spending has followed a similar path. As illustrated in Figure 2, R&D expenditures—measured in inflation-adjusted dollars—have never been higher. Though R&D spending by the public sector, while rising through the 1980s, has been declining through the 90s, spending by U.S. industry has doubled since 1980.  Note that Figure 1 shows only domestic patents—that is, those patents applied for and granted to U.S. companies, institutions and individuals, typically about 55-60% percent of total patenting. As shown in Figure 3, on page 61, the overall trend is the same—from 315,015 applications, total patent grants numbered 175,983 in the year 2000, including 85,072 domestic utility patents, 72,425 foreign utility patents, 17,414 design patents, 548 plant patents, and 524 reissues.  Part III.  Concerning  the Effects on  1960  Innovation  1965  1970  Figure 1 :  19SS  1960  1965  1975  1980  198S  1990  U . S . Patent Activity (Domestic)  1970  1975  1980  1985  1990  1995  4  1995  Figure 2: U . S . Research & Development Spending  47  2000  2000  4  Sources: United States Patent & Trademark Office, http://www.uspto.gov/; Jaffe, supra note 24, at 54, Fig. 1; Robert M. Hunt, "Patent Reform: A Mixed Blessing for the U.S. Economy?" (Dec. 1999) Federal Reserve Philadelphia  48  Bank  Business Review at 17, Fig. 2.  Sources: National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resources Studies, http://www.nsf.gov/sbe/srs/; Jaffe, ibid, at 54, Fig. 1; Hunt, ibid, at 16, Fig. 1.  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on  Innovation  18  Thus, the increases in both patenting and R&D activity seem to be prima facie evidence that a stronger patent system does indeed foster innovation. Shortly after the policy changes of the early 1980s, patenting by U.S. inventors began to skyrocket. At about the same time, spending on research and development started its upward march. If innovation can be measured by patent activity or R&D spending, then surely the policy changes of the last twenty years have been successful. On closer examination of Figures 1 and 2, however, we see that while the surge in patenting began in the mid-1980s, the increase in R&D spending started in the mid-70s. This suggests that while the increase in patenting may be due to changes in the patent system, it seems that the increase in research and development spending—or at least the beginning of it—is unrelated to those changes. Furthermore, the decade-long lag between the upturn in R&D and the upturn in patenting is too long to be consistent with evidence showing that there is little or no lag between changes in R&D spending and changes in patent application rates.  49  One might expect that it might take some time for  money spent on research and development to manifest itself in the form of patentable inventions, but not that long. This suggests that the increase in R&D spending is not correlated to the increase in patenting. We need to take a closer look at what actually caused the surge in U.S. patenting, and how exactly patents are related to research and development spending.  Bronwyn Hall, Zvi Griliches & Jerry Hausman, "Patents and R&D: Is There a Lag?" (1986) 27 Intl. Econ. Rev. 26S.  Part III. Concerning  A.  the Effects on  19  Innovation  The Pa ten t Surge  The most thorough analysis of U.S. patenting trends to date is that of Samuel Kortum and Josh Lerner.  50  In their 1997 National Bureau of Economic Research paper, the authors consider four  possible explanations for the unprecedented surge in patenting. The first is what they call the "friendly court" hypothesis—that, as discussed above, the doctrinal modifications made by the Federal Circuit have made patents more valid, and hence increased the so-called propensity to patent of U.S. inventors.  Not all inventions are patented, nor even all  potentially-patentable ones. Inventors balance the time and expense of the patent process—and the possible loss of secrecy that results from patent publication—against the protection that a patent potentially affords to the invention.  The "friendly court" of the Federal Circuit, posit Kortum and.  Lerner, has increased the probability of success in obtaining and defending a patent and has therefore shifted that balance, causing a higher proportion of potentially-patentable inventions to be patented. A variant of the friendly court hypothesis sees the changes of the 1980s as an example of "regulatory capture"—that the large firms which dominated the research and patenting processes in the United States managed to induce the government to change the rules in their favour, making patenting easier.  Under this theory, the increase in patenting would be dominated by those firms, taking  advantage of the new environment they had created. The third hypothesis is that a shift in technological opportunity has made more invention possible.  This "fertile technology" theory points particularly to the new areas of biotechnology and  information technologies as the source of the patent surge.  Surely, opening these new frontiers to  patenting must account for some of the growth in patenting.  Kortum & Lerner, "Stronger Protection or Technological Revolution: What is Behind the Recent Surge in Patenting?" (1997) National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W6204.  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on  20  Innovation  The fourth, and perhaps least likely, supposition considered by Kortum and Lerner is that the process of research and invention has become more productive, either by changes in research technology, such as the application of computers and advanced statistics to problems that had previously been handled heuristically, or by changes in the management of the research process, including an emphasis on the kind of applied research that is likely to generate patents. To distinguish among these hypotheses, the authors look at the patent data in several ways. First, they posit that the "friendly court" theory suggests that U.S. patents should have become more valuable for all inventors, both domestic and foreign. Thus, we should see an increase in patenting in the United States by foreigners roughly equal to the increase by domestic inventors. This hypothesis also suggests an increase in the propensity to patent in the United States only, and not in other countries—where the patent systems have remained relatively unchanged—and so U.S. inventors should not necessarily have increased their rate of patenting in other countries. Neither of these implications, however, is borne out by the data. Patenting by foreign entities in the U.S. has increased, but it was increasing rapidly before the 1980s, and there was no sign of acceleration after the creation of the Federal Circuit in 1982.  Furthermore, patenting by American  inventors has increased abroad. An analysis of the United States and other industrialized countries as both "sources" and "destinations" for patent applications showed the U.S. has become a significantly greater source, but not a more important destination. Surprisingly, this clearly suggests that the brave new era of patenting ushered in by the Federal Circuit is not the primary explanation for the surge in U.S. patenting activity. Kortum and Lerner also show that the data doesn't support the "fertile technology" or the "regulatory capture" hypotheses either.  After a comprehensive analysis based on the international  patent classification (IPC) system, they found that biotechnology patents grew from 3% of all patents in 1969 to about 6% in 1991, and that software increased from 4% to almost 7% over the same period.  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on  21  Innovation  The authors found, however, that this kind of growth wasn't confined just to the new technologies— approximately 70% of all patent classes exhibited an increased rate of patenting. Similarly, the increase was not confined to those firms which had traditionally dominated the patenting process.  On the  contrary, the growth in patenting was skewed toward those firms which previously had relatively few patents. Through this process of elimination, Kortum and Lerner conclude that there must have been an increase in the productivity of the research process, at least in terms of its ability to produce the kind of innovation that leads to patents.  The most unlikely of the causes set forth—the so-called  "managerial process" theory—seems to be the primary reason for the patent surge of the past decade. The authors go on to ask whether an increase in the productivity of research is consistent with the observed behaviour of research and development expenditure, and develop a simple model of research-driven economic growth in which an unexpected permanent increase in the productivity of R&D is predicted to lead to a transitory increase in R&D as well as patents.  The difficulty with  reconciling this prediction with the data is that, as noted above, R&D began its increase so much sooner that patenting. If research productivity began to increase in the 1970s, there should have been an effect on patenting rates within a few years. Thus, the inference of Kortum and Lerner's careful analysis is that the explanation for the patent surge lies largely outside the patent system, despite the coincidence of timing with momentous changes in patent policy. Much of the increase in patenting can be associated with an increase in real R&D spending that began much earlier, and much of the rest can be attributed to "improvements in the management or automation of the innovation process itself. "  S1  The strengthening of the patent system  did, presumably, reinforce these initiatives—i.e., it is possible that the R&D boom would not have been so large or lasted so long without this reinforcement—but there appears to be little or no  31  /t/at 4 .  Part III.  Concerning  the Effects on  22  Innovation  empirical evidence that strengthening and extending U.S. intellectual property protection resulted in any significant changes to the innovation process. Studies by other economists have also failed to find evidence that the strengthening of patent rights during the 1980s directly stimulated industrial spending in research and development. Robert Hunt of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia recently examined the market valuation of R&D investments made by a dozen U.S. semiconductors companies from 1976 to 1994 and found that while there was a significant increase in the market value of those investments, it occurred after 1989—more than five years after the significance of the changes in the patent system were widely known.  52  A more  recent study by James Bessen and Eric Maskin at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology showed that rather than increasing, real R&D intensity (defined as R&D spending relative to sales) in information technology-related industries—including semiconductors, telecommunications and computers—has fallen steadily since about 1982.  B.  53  The Patent Paradox  This lack of correlation between stronger patent rights and increased R&D spending is reinforced by survey evidence. A 1983 study by Levin, Klevorick, Nelson and Winter at Yale University asked R&D managers across various manufacturing industries about the effectiveness of different mechanisms for appropriating the returns to research and development.  52  53  54  Somewhat surprisingly, they found that the  See Hunt, supra note 47, at 24. Bessen & Maskin, "Sequential Innovation, Patents, and Imitation" (January 2000) Working Paper No. 00-01, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Similarly, a study by economist Bronwyn Hall at the University of California, Berkeley found that the market value of R&D investment made by about 1000 publicly-traded companies increased through most of the 1970s, began to decline after 1983, and then rose again around 1990. Hall, "Industrial Research During the 1980s: Did the Rate of Return Fall?" Brookings Microeconomics  54  Papers:  (1993) 289.  Levin, Klevorick, Nelson & Winter, "Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and Development" (1987) 3 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 783. The authors surveyed 1,478 R&D labs in 43 industries. In an earlier study, Schercr had also found that respondents did not consider patents to be particularly important in  Part III. Concerning  23  the Effects on Innovation  protection from imitation offered by patents was seen as a relatively unimportant source of incentives for technological innovation.  55  Instead, lead time and quality of service were perceived as far more  useful tools for recouping R&D expenditures, as shown below.  Table 1: Effectiveness Rankings of Various Appropriability Mechanisms 1983 Yale Survey  1994 Carnegie Mellon Survey  Number of Industries  Number of Industries  Ranking Mechanism as:  Ranking Mechanism as:  1st  2nd  3rd  4th  Mechanism  1st  2nd  3rd  4th  5th  Patents  S  6  20  13  Patents  14  14  7  8  1  Secrecy  0  0  19  25  Secrecy  3  4  5  12  20  Lead Time  17  21  6  0  Lead Time  22  6  10  4  2  Sales & Service  24  19  1  0  Sales & Service  3  9  11  15  6  Manufacturing  4  14  13  7  6  Mechanism  Table 1 also shows the results of a 1994 follow-up study administered by Cohen, Nelson and Walsh at Carnegie Mellon University.  56  Although patents were ranked higher, first-mover advantages were still  seen to be the most effective way to appropriate returns on investment.  Thus the so-called "patent  paradox"—that despite the fact that firms are taking out so many more patents, R&D managers do not perceive patents to be much more effective than they did over a decade before. What could explain this paradox? Cohen and his co-authors suggest that the reconciliation of the exponential rise in patenting and the modest increase in their perceived effectiveness may lie in the multiple ways that firms use patents.  In particular, their survey shows that in addition to protecting the returns to specific  R&D decision making—except when patent lawyers prepared the responses. F.M. Scherer, The Economic of Compulsory 5 5  5 6  Licensing(N.Y.U.,  Effects  1977) at 36-37.  See Scherer, supra note 45. Cohen, Nelson & Walsh, "Protecting Their Intellectual Assets: Appropriability Conditions and Why U.S. Manufacturing Firms Patent (or Not)" (2000) National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W7552.  Part III.  Concerning  the Effects on  24  Innovation  inventions, firms also use patents to block their competitors' products, as bargaining chips in crosslicensing negotiations, and to prevent or defend against infringement suits. It is possible, says Gohen, that the respondents didn't consider these benefits of patents when evaluating the effectiveness of patents in protecting their investments in innovation.  C.  Semiconductor Patenting  These suppositions are supported by the work of Bronwyn Hall and Rosemarie Ham-Ziedonis. Intrigued by the Levin and Cohen studies, they embarked on a detailed examination of the one industry where the contrast between the increase in patenting and perceived unimportance of patenting as a means of securing returns to innovation was the strongest—the semiconductor industry.  57  Indeed, in  both surveys, R&D managers in semiconductor companies consistently reported that patents were among the least effective mechanisms for appropriating returns to R&D investments.  Driven by the  rapid pace of technological change and short product life-cycles, semiconductor firms tend to rely more heavily on lead time, secrecy, and manufacturing or design capabilities than any other industry. And yet the surge in patenting was highest in the semiconductor industry. Even accounting for increases in research and development spending, Hall and Ham-Ziedonis found that the propensity for semiconductor firms to patent essentially doubled between 1982 and 1992.  58  In order to illuminate the factors underpinning the semiconductor patent surge and the effects of stronger patent rights on the innovative activities of semiconductor firms, the two researchers  5 7  Hall & Ham-Ziedonis, "The Patent Paradox Revisited: An Empirical Study of Patenting in the U.S. Semiconductor Industry, 1979-95" (2000) Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley.  58  Realizing that increases in research and development spending are correlated to patenting rates, Hall and HamZiedonis normalized the patenting rate as a function of R&D expenditures to find patent yields (or propensities), i.e., the number of successful patent applications per million dollars of R&D spent (in constant 1992 dollars). Doing the same for other industries, they found that the patent surge in semiconductors was exceptional—while patent yields in computing and electronics rose slightly, yields for manufacturing as a whole was fairly stagnant and those for pharmaceuticals actually declined over the same period.  Part III. Concerning  25  the Effects on Innovation  employed a two-fold research strategy.  First, they conducted interviews with intellectual property  managers and executives from several U.S. semiconductor firms—both traditional manufacturers and the newer, specialized design firms, most of whom entered the industry during the period associated with stronger patent rights.  Second, they performed a quantitative econometric analysis of a much  larger sample of such firms, including the compilation of a detailed database of their patent portfolios from the period 1975 to 1998. Like Kortum and Lerner, Hall and Ham-Ziedonis found that much of the increase in patenting was due to managerial improvements.  But whereas Kortum and Lerner concluded that the patent  surge was caused by managerial change in the research and development process, Hall and HamZiedohis found that the change was far more focused on managing the patenting process itself. The . large-scale manufacturers they talked to spoke of "ramping up" their patent portfolios and "harvesting" latent inventions to add to their stock of patents. One firm they interviewed had gone from owning a total of 30 patents in 1990 to filing over 300 patents in one year, with an internal goal in place to "own 1000 patents by the year 2000."  59  Many firms had established "patent advocacy committees" that work  with the company's engineers, making sure they identified more of the patentable inventions and getting those inventions to the patent office, while minimizing the amount of time it took for engineers to be involved in the patent process. Not all patenting, however, could be traced to managerial improvements. Two events, both indirectly related to the more favourable judicial treatment of U.S. patent rights—the "friendly court"—were frequently mentioned as having played a pivotal role in reshaping the patent strategies of the  firms they  interviewed.  60  First and foremost,  interviewees emphasized  "demonstration effect" of the huge damages award in the Polaroid  5 9  60  the important  v. Kodak case, and the realization  Id. at 11  The authors note that Kortum and Lerner's use of aggregate (international vs. domestic), rather than firm-level, data may have led them to dismiss the effects of the "pro-patent" ("friendly-court") shift too quickly, at least in the context of the semiconductor industry where the surge in patenting was most dramatic. Id. at 9.  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on  26  Innovation  that courts were willing to take an aggressive stance against infringement by halting—either temporarily or permanently—production that used infringed technologies.  For a high-volume  fabrication facility costing billions of dollars, a preliminary injunction is prohibitively expensive, perhaps costing millions of dollars per week in lost revenue. A second widely-cited reason was referred to as the "TI" effect.  During mid-1980s, Texas  Instruments had successfully asserted various patents on integrated circuits and manufacturing methods and was thereafter able to charge higher royalty rates for their patents.  Other companies such as  AT&T, IBM and Motorola quickly followed suit, and now most large-scale firms use their patent portfolios as assets with which to generate significant revenues. Revenues from patent licenses in the United States soared from about $ 15 billion in 1990 to more than $100 billion in 1998.  61  IBM alone  took in well over $1 billion'from licensing in 1999, and received a record 2,756 new patents.  62  Citing these effects, interviewees at the manufacturingfirmsnoted that patents had become far more important as bargaining chips in negotiations with other firms. Because of the "systems" nature of semiconductor technology, it is virtually impossible to make products that do not incorporate the technology of other firms, and so everyone needs cross-licensing arrangements, both to gain entry into the market and to avoid infringement suits.  One industry executive estimated that without a patent  portfolio with which to bargain, a new manufacturer would need to spend $100 to $200 million just to license what are now considered basic manufacturing principles.  63  Although such agreements had  always been fairly common in the industry, the strengthening of patent protection in the 1980s 64  brought new attention to the value of patent portfolios.  61  James Gleick, "Patently Absurd" N. V. Times (12 March 2000) at 6-44.  6 2  Id.  63  Id. at 13—citing Michael Rostoker, former vice president of strategic alliances at LSI Logic.  6 4  In 1981, Intel Chief Counsel Roger S. Borovoy was quoted as saying, "In the electronics industry, patents are of no value whatsoever in spurring research and development. We use them because we have to. You can't be the only holdout against the angry hordes or else you pay everyone." See "The Patent is Expiring as a Spur to Innovation"  Part III. Concerning  27  the Effects on Innovation  Even where cross-licensing agreements were not in place beforehand, it appears that firms look at their portfolios as a kind of post facto protection from infringement suits. James Rose, former inhouse counsel at both Sun Microsystems and programmable logic-chip maker Altera, tells the story of getting a phone call from an engineer asking, "You know, I would like to use this circuit or technology, but I think some other company has a patent on it. What should we do?" Surprisingly, most of the time Mr. Rose would answer, "Don't worry about it."  65  Though this may seem like an irresponsible response from a patent counsel, his stance seems justified. The fact that in the semiconductor field there are literally tens of thousands of patents and that "any given product probably infringes 10, 20, 30, maybe more of those patents.  If a company  were to spend all of its time trying to figure out and design around patents, they would never get a product out the door." The other factor, explained Mr. Rose, was that "because we were filing and protecting our own innovations [but] also filing in areas that were outside of our scope of technology . . . the hope or the expectation was, if this particular company did find out about the infringement, we would hopefully be able to go to our own portfolio" and find a patent that the other company is infringing. That, he said, "gave us the freedom to design the best product and not necessarily worry about other companies' patents."  66  To that end, he spoke of the quest by semiconductor firms to build  patent portfolios as a "frenzy to file" or an "arms race" with a "mutually-assured destruction (MAD) mentality."  67  The story was quite different for the smaller firms in the study, however.  Hall and Ham-  Ziedonis found that the period of increased patenting coincided with a time of significant entry by new firms into the industry, many of which were so-called "fab-less" manufacturers who design computer  Business Week(\ 1 May 1981) at 44E. Apparently the ineffectiveness of patents as recouping returns on investment was a commonplace phenomenon even then. 65  James Rose, Presentation to the National Academics' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), Intellectual  6 6  Id.  Property  Rights: How Far Should They Be Extended? {2-3 February 2000: Washington, DC).  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on  28  Innovation  chips but contract the manufacturing to others. This separation of design from manufacture, and the resulting reduction in the barriers to entry into chip design, would not have been possible if the design firms could not protect their creations from appropriation by the large manufacturers. For such companies, patents also play a critical role in attracting capital, specifically venture capital. A number of design firms said that in order to secure funding, venture capitalists demanded that they protect their inventions with strong patent rights that would stand up in court. James Rose also underscored the importance of patents to VCs, saying that patents are particularly necessary in Silicon Valley, where there is so much start-up activity. Venture capitalists almost always look to see if a new company has patent applications, and frequently hire patent attorneys to determine if they are likely to issue. Investment decisions can often be based almost entirely on the strength of a start-up's intellectual property.  D.  Software Patenting  The software industry shares many of the problems found in semiconductors. Martin Konopken, inhouse counsel at the software firm Autodesk, Inc., the fourth largest PC software company in theworld, echoes the comments of James Rose when he lays out what he sees as the main problem with software patents. The typical software program has thousands of functions and hundreds of important features.  With over 100,000 software patents now issued, Konopken estimates that large products,  such as Autodesk's AutoCAD program, may infringe up to ten thousand of those.  Searching all of  them, he says, is impossible, especially since software patents are notoriously difficult to interpret, often requiring patent counsel to examine their prosecution histories.  Id.  Add to that the typical 18-  29  Part III. Concerning the Effects on Innovation  month product cycle and the pressure to get a product out the door as soon as possible, and the rule for software companies, says Mr. Konopken, "is not to search, because you simply can't."  68  And so the end result is what he calls a game of "gotcha"—in which certain companies use patent litigation as a way to make money. They have a patent, and they look around for someone in the software industry who has inadvertently infringed it. Once a product is on the market, it's very hard to modify, since customers get used to certain features and don't want them changed. So most software companies fight the infringement suit. "If you don't either slam dunk the other side, or settle, then you go to court," says Konopken, "where a patent case costs $2 million to fight, plus your engineers' time.. It is really a game of extortion in many cases." For Mr. Konopken and others, the advent of software patenting has not been a good thing: "I speak with my fellow in-house counsel in the software industry frequently. There is an amazing degree of unanimity about software patents. We all hate them."  69  Unlike semiconductors, however, software has not always been patentable.  Yet while the  twenty-five year-long debate over software patentability is finally over, the effects of that controversy still linger. By focusing everyone's attention on the subject-matter issue, and giving lip service to the idea that software per se was unpatentable well into the 1990s, a climate was created in which the actual patenting of software was largely ignored.  70  This has had a number of important consequences  unique to the software industry.  Martin Konopken, Presentation to the National Academies' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), Intellectual Property Rights: Mow Ear Should They Be Extended? (2-3 February 2000: Washington, DC). Id. As discussed above, though the Supreme Court's decision in Diehr opened the door to software patenting, somewhat creative drafting was required to ensure that the software in question operated in the context of an "otherwise statutory" industrial process—see supra note 15.  Part III.  Concerning  30  the Effects on Innovation  First, while volumes have been written about whether software should or should not be patentable,  71  there has been a very limited discussion of other validity issues such as obviousness,  enablement, or best mode.  72  In addition to being novel, useful and nonobvious under sections 102 and  103, a valid patent must meet the disclosure requirements of the first paragraph of section 112: The specification shall contain a written description of the invention, and of the manner and process of making and using it, in such full, clear, concise, and exact terms as to enable any person skilled in the art to which it pertains, or with which it is most nearly connected, to make and use the same, and shall set forth the best mode contemplated by the inventor of carrying out his invention.  73  As suggested by the emphasis, the above paragraph is generally interpreted as calling for three separate requirements:  (1) the description requirement; (2) the enablement requirement; and (3) the best  mode requirement. The description requirement requires all of the claims in a patent to be supported by an adequate description of the claimed invention in the patent's specification.  74  The enablement  requirement places an obligation on the patent applicant to provide a sufficiently clear explanation of the invention that would enable a person having ordinary skill in the art to make and use the invention .  Bookshelves verily groan under the weight. One commentator estimates that from 1970-79, over 200 academic articles were devoted to the patenting of computer programs; from 1980-89, there were over SOO; and from 19902000, well over 1,000 articles were written. See James P. Chandler, "Patent Protection of Computer Programs" (2000) 1 Minn. Intell. Prop. Rev. 2 at4 n.15. For some of the more influential of these, see Pamela A. Samuelson, "Benson Revisited: The Case Against Patent Protection for Algorithms and Other Computer-Related Inventions" (1990) 39 Emory L.J. 1025; Richard H. Stern, "Tales from the Algorithm War: Bensonto  Iwahashi, It's Deja Vu  All Over Again" (1991) 18 AIPLA Q.J. 371; Jur Strobos, "Stalking the Elusive Patentable Software: Are there still Diehror  was it just a FlookT (1993) 6 Harv. J. of Law & Tech. 363; Maximilian R. Peterson, "Now You See It,  Now You Don't: Was It a Patentable Machine or an Unpatentable 'Algorithm'? On Principle and Expediency in Current Patent Law Doctrines Relating to Computer-Implemented Inventions" (1995) 64 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 90. Discussion came only after the Federal Circuit began deciding such issues. See, e.g., Lockwood Airlines,  107 F.3d 1565 (Fed. Cir. 1997); In re Zurko,  11 F.3d 887 (Fed. Cir. 1997); Fonarv.  v. American General  Electric  Co., 107F.3d 1543 (Fed. Cir. 1997); In re Dossel, 115 F.3d942 (Fed. Cir. 1997). 35 U.S.C. § 112 (1994). The second paragraph of 112 requires that "the specification shall conclude with one or more claims particularly pointing out and distinctly claiming the subject matter which the applicant regards as his invention." Id. This imposes a requirement of definiteness for each claim in the patent—a claim will be considered definite if it reasonably describes the claimed invention to those skilled in the art and if it serves to distinguish the claim over the prior art. See Andrew In rc Wertheim,  Corp. v. GabrielElecs.,  Inc., 847 F.2d 819 at 821 (Fed. Cir. 1988).  541 F.2d 257 at 262 (CCPA 1976). The description requirement usually becomes an issue when a  claim is added by the patent applicant at some time after the original filing date of the application  31  Part III. Concerning the Effects on Innovation  without undue experimentation.  75  The disclosure of section 112 is complete when the inventor reveals  the "best mode" he or she knows for practicing the invention.  76  Disclosure, in a sense, is the price an inventor pays for patent protection. In exchange for its grant of monopoly, the government demands that an inventor reveal the inner workings of his invention so that others can understand it and possibly improve on it. Thus the patent system's classic quid pro quo—disclosure is the quo for which the inventor receives his quid, the monopoly grant. Unfortunately, however, it seems that the level of disclosure in software patents is severely lacking. As Pamela Samuelson, Professor of Law and Information Management at the University of California, Berkeley, has said, "we are getting lots of quid but no quo." Despite years of contact with people in the software industry, she claims that she has "never talked to anybody who, in the process of development, actually reads patents in order to get informed."  77  Other problems are more critical. Since software was not officially patentable until the mid908, the Patent Office only recently began to hire patent examiners qualified in computer software or related fields.  78  During the 1980s and early part of the 90s, the lion's share of software patent  applications were handled by examiners operating outside their areas of expertise. For similar reasons, the PTO's classification system has been ill-equipped to handle software patents. In the past, patents have tended to be classified according to the field in which the software would ultimately be used—for example, making pizzas or curing rubber—rather than the nature of the software invention itself. This  The enablement requirement will be met even if some experimentation is required, so long as that experimentation is not undue. In re Barker, 559 F.2d 588 at 591 (C.C.P.A 1977) The analysis of the best mode requirement involves two questions: (1) did the inventor know of a better mode of carrying out the claimed invention than that disclosed in the specification?; and (2) did the inventor conceal that better mode? Chemcast Corp. v. Arco Indus. Corp., 913 F.2d 923 at 927 (Fed. Cir. 1990). Pamela Samuelson, Presentation to the National Academies' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), Intellectual Property Rights: How Far Should They Be Extended? {l-l February 2000: Washington, DC). See Scott Thurm, "A Flood of Web Patents Stirs Dispute Over Tactics" Wall St. Journal'(9 October 1998) at BI — asserting that the PTO didn't hire its first examiner with a degree in computer science until 1995.  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on  32  Innovation  has made it much harder for examiners to find what prior art exists for a certain invention, and thus to determine whether it is novel. Under section 102 of the U.S. Patent Act, an inventor may not receive a patent if the invention already exists in the "prior art"—that is, if the invention is patented or described in a printed or online publication anywhere in the world before the date on which the inventor files his or her patent application.  79  In practically every field that the Patent Office covers, examiners determine whether an  invention is new by searching two kinds of computerized databases: the PTO's own Automated Patent System, which tracks the more than six million patents issued since 1790, and the so-called Electronic Information Center, which includes nearly every commercially-available database of scientific literature. For most technologies, this works fine. But unlike more established engineering fields such as semiconductors and even biotechnology, most software inventions are not described in industry publications. Instead, computer science academics commonly save up their best work for big textbook projects, and few publishers have allowed the full text of their books to be incorporated into online databases. And a lot of software prior art might not be written down at all. As the ex-commissioner of patents and trademarks, Bruce Lehman, once admitted, "We search the patent database, both U.S. and foreign, and search every commercial database.  But there are many concepts that have been done  which are what I call folklore. They are out there, and people know about them, but we can't find any written documentation. The examination process requires that we have written documentation which we can point to which states a particular fact. Too often we can't find the documentation. Then when the patent is issued, some people say, 'Well, this is well-known, it has been in the industry for  35 U.S.C. § 102 (1994). See also 37 C.F.R. 1.104(a) (1997), requiring the patent examiner to "make a thorough investigation of the available prior art relating to the subject matter of the claimed invention." Simson L. Garfinkel, "Patently Absurd" WiredQuly 1994) 104 at 107.  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on Innovation  33  This is a main criticism of software patents—that the Patent Office has issued (and is issuing) patents which are far from novel. Examples of such patents are commonly pointed out by Gregory Aharonian, a vocal critic of software patents for the past ten years via his Internet Patent News Service. He cites U.S. Patent No. 5,865,827, describing a "device and method to provide a gateway for the transfer of information between financial markets and customers." It was issued on 26 January 1996, despite the fact that a speaker at a computing conference in 1985 had presented a paper on the exact same thing.  81  Likewise, on 6 July 1993, the Patent Office issued a patent for an "Automated Health  Benefit Processing System" whereby the system asks patients a few questions and enters the answers into their records, despite the fact that throughout the 1980s there were yearly conferences with, lengthy proceedings on the very same topic.  82  Other patents seem far too broad. Take U.S. Patent No. 5,173,051, issued to Optical Data Corporation of Warren, New Jersey on 22 December 1992, describing a system for "curriculum planning and publishing" using a computer and a videodisc player. If enforced, such a patent would make out millions of teachers to be infringers.  O r consider Patent No. 5,105,184, the so-called  "Energizer Bunny Patent," issued in 1992 to Software Advertising Corp.  It covers "displaying and  integrating commercial advertisements with computer software"—in other words, any advertisement integrated into a screen saver. Another common criticism is that the companies getting all of the patents are not the ones doing the innovating. According to Aharonian, in 1998, IBM held 1200 software patents, far more than the runners-up, Motorola (with 360), Fujitsu (with 330), and Canon (330).  83  None of these  companies is considered an innovative software maker. Microsoft is next on Aharonian's list (with  81  Gregory Aharonian, Presentation to the National Academies' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), Intellectual  82  8 3  Property Rights: How Far Should They Be Extended?'(2-3 February 2000: Washington, DC).  Id. Aharonian, "1998 U.S. software patent statistics" Internet posting (23 July 1999), available on-line at http://www.aful.org/pipermail/patents/1999-July/00004S.html.  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on  34  Innovation  310) but only because they've been playing some serious catch-up—in 1992, they held only 13 patents.  84  The companies that collectively constituted the microcomputer revolution, companies  such as Borland, Novell, Adobe, Lotus, NeXT, Intel, Apple, Sun, and SGI, have all had relatively weak software patent portfolios. IBM, critics claim, has a very strong patent portfolio only because it has "patented every single trivial idea every employee ever comes up with, rather than having any great propensity to be truly innovative."  85  Indeed, IBM even has a patent, number 5,247,661, on a software application to permit  employees to automatically document ideas for later patenting.  86  And in 1999, nearly 30 years after  :  the production of the IBM 370, a minicomputer with rotary switches on the front for selecting applications and data entry functionality, IBM got a patent for sticking a rotary switch on the front of a PC—for choosing functions such as Program Manager, Notepad, Calculator, Paintbrush, Solitaire, or Minesweeper:  E.  87  Business Method Patenting  Lately, however, the concerns of the semiconductor and software industries have been overshadowed by the controversy surrounding business method patenting. As mentioned, in the 1998 case of State  8 4  Gordon Irlam & Ross Williams, "Negative Correlation of Innovation and Software Patents" (January 1994) Revised version of Appendix D of the League for Programming Freedom's submission to the U.S. Patent Office, available on-line at http://www.base.com/software-patents/scoreboard.html. Apparently, Microsoft hasn't slowed its pace—a 27 November 2001 search of the PTO Web site for patents assigned to Microsoft revealed 1,785 patents (though a portion of those are for hardware inventions).  8 5  Id.  8 6  Id.  8 7  Aharonian, supra note 81. U.S. Patent Number 5,973,666, "Method and Means for Controlling the Concurrent Execution of a Plurality of Programs on a Computer System." The first page of the patent actually shows a dial with 16 settings, from Program Manager (0) to MS-DOS Window (12)—positions 13 to 15 are left blank, presumably for additional applications.  Part III. Concerning  35  the Effects on Innovation  Street Bank v. Signature Financial Group, the Federal Circuit had not only eliminated what was left of the software debate, it had endorsed the patenting of so-called methods of doing business.  88  Signature Financial Group held the patent disputed in that case.  89  Directed to a "Data  Processing System for Hub and Spoke Financial Services Configuration," it described a data processing system for implementing an investment structure known as a "Hub and Spoke" system.  This system  allowed individual mutual funds (spokes) to pool their assets in an investment portfolio (hub) organized as a partnership.  According to the patent, such an investment regime provided the advantageous  combination of economies of scale in administering investments coupled with the tax advantages of a partnership.  90  Following issuance of the patent, Signature entered into licensing negotiations with a competitor, State Street Bank, that ultimately proved unsuccessful.  State Street then brought a  declaratory judgment action against Signature, seeking the invalidity of the patent. The district court granted summary judgment in favor of State Street under two alternative grounds.  91  The first was based on what the district court termed as the "mathematical algorithm/physical transformation test," or the Freeman-Walter-Abele test.  92  The district court found that Signature's  patent claim failed this test because there was no physical transformation or reduction taking place, concluding that:  88  State Street Bank & Trust Co. v. Signature Financial  8 9  United States Patent No. 5,193,056 (9 March 1993).  9 0  91  9 2  Group, Inc., 149 F.3d 1368 (Fed. Cir. 1998).  Id. State Street Bank & Trust Co. v. Signature Financial  Group, Inc., 927 F. Supp. 502 (D. Mass. 1996).  The test had been developed by the Federal Circuit's predecessor, the Court of Customs and Patent Appeals, following the Supreme Court judgment in Diamond  v. Diehr.  See supra note 13; In re Abele, 684 F.2d 902 (CCPA  1982); In re Walter, 618 F.2d 758 (CCPA 1980); In re Freeman, 573 F.2d 1237 (CCPA 1978). Under the first part of the test, a patent must recite, either directly or indirectly, a mathematical algorithm. Under the "physical transformation" part of the test, the court then must determine whether the claimed invention is applied to or limited by physical elements or process steps, or, in the words of the district court, "regardless of whether the invention performs mathematical operations, if it transforms or reduces subject matter to a different state or thing, it is statutory under 101." State Street, 927 F. Supp. at 51 3.  Part III.  Concerning  the Effects on  36  Innovation  At bottom, the invention is an accounting system for a certain type of financial investment vehicle claimed as means for performing a series of mathematical functions.  Quite simply, it involves no  further physical transformation or reduction than inputting numbers, calculating numbers, outputting numbers, and storing numbers. The same functions could be performed, albeit less efficiently, by an accountant armed with pencil, paper, calculator, and a filing system.  93  The district court then buttressed its holding by turning to "the long-established principle that business 'plans' and 'systems' are not patentable."  94  After reviewing the case law and treatises  supporting this "business methods exception," the court reasoned that to allow the patent in question 95  would, in effect, grant Signature a monopoly on the idea of a multi-tiered portfolio-investment structure.  96  The Federal Circuit reversed the district court on both the mathematical algorithm exception and the business method exception as to unpatentable subject matter. Writing for a three-judge panel, Judge Giles Rich first addressed the mathematicalalgorithrn exception, finding that the district court erred in applying the inconsistent Freeman-Walter-Abele analysis, explaining that "after Diehr and i Chakrabarty;the Freeman-Walter-Abele test has little, if any, applicability to determining the presence of statutory subject matter."  97  Rather, the court asserted that "whether a claim encompasses statutory  Id. at 515. Id. Id. at 515-16. See Loew'sDrive-In  Theatres, Inc. v. Park-In Theatres, Inc., 174 F.2d 547 at 552 (1st Cir. 1949);  Hotel Sec. Checking Co. v. Lorraine Co., 160 F. 467 at 469 (2d Cir. 1908) ("A system of transacting business disconnected from the means of carrying out the system is not, within the most liberal interpretation of the term, an art."); E.B. Lipscomb, Lipscomb's  Walker on Patents 2:17 (3d ed. 1984) at 171. The business methods  exception developed as an extension of the prescription on patenting abstract principles. As early as 1868, the Patent Commissioner sensed that "it is contrary to the spirit of the law . . . to grant patents for methods of bookkeeping": Ex parte Abraham,  1868 Dec. Comm'r Pat. 59. Nineteenth century courts also opined that "a method of  transacting common business" and "a mere contract" were unpatentable: United States Credit Sys. Co. v. American Credit Indemnity Co., S3 F. 818 at 819 ( C C S . D . N . Y . 1893); In re Moescr,  27 App. D.C. 307 at 310 (1906)  The court judged that "patenting an accounting system necessary to carry on a certain type of business is tantamount to a patent on the business itself. Because such abstract ideas are not patentable, either as methods of doing business or as mathematical algorithms," the patent was held invalid. Id. at 516. State Street Bank, supra note 88. Though Judge Rich was reputedly the principal drafter of the 1952 Patent Act and the longest-sitting federal judge at the time, this statement shows little sense of history—Diehr was, decided in 1981  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on  37  Innovation  subject matter should not focus on which of the four categories of subject matter a claim is directed to ... but rather, on the essential characteristics of the subject matter, in particular, its practical utility."  98  Significantly, the Federal Circuit held that the transformation of data could constitute a practical application of an algorithm to qualify for a patent, and explained, "today, we hold that the transformation of data, representing discrete dollar amounts, by a machine through a series of mathematical calculations into a final share price, constitutes a practical application of a mathematical algorithm, formula, or calculation, because it produces 'a useful, concrete and tangible result'."  99  Signature's "Hub and Spoke" software satisfied the test under section 101 because it produced a final share price, momentarily fixed for recording and reporting purposes, and that final share price was considered a "useful, concrete, and tangible result."  100  Despite the presence of a mathematical  algorithm, the usefulness of the software rendered it patentable under the Patent Act, reasoned the court, even though the useful result was "expressed in numbers, such as price, profit, percentage, cost, or loss."  101  Accordingly, in order for an invention employing an algorithm to be patentable, it is not  necessary that the transformation be limited to physical matter. Overruling the district court's holding as to the business method exception, Judge Rich embraced "the opportunity to lay this ill-conceived exception to rest," asserting that "since the 1952 Patent Act, business methods have been, and should have been, subject to the same legal requirements for patentability as applied to any other process or method."  102  Moreover, neither the Federal Circuit  nor its predecessor court, the CCPA, had ever invoked the business method exception to deem an  and Abele was decided in 1982. See John R. Thomas, "The Post-Industrial Patent System" (1999) 10 Fordham I.P., Media & Ent. L.J. 3 at 25-26, for other reasons why "State Streetis a curious opinion on a number of fronts." Id. Id. at 1373. Id. at 1375.  Part III.  Concerning  the Effects on  invention unpatentable.  103  38  Innovation  When this exception has been applied, said the court, it had been after a  "ruling based on some clearer concept of Title 35 or ... on finding a mathematical algorithm." The Federal Circuit found additional support in the PTO's position on the business method exception.  It contrasted the 1994 Examination Guidelines, which instructed that "though seemingly  within the category of process or method, a method of doing business can be rejected as not being within the statutory classes," with the 1996 Guidelines, which omitted this exclusionary language and stated that methods of doing business should be treated like any other process claims.  104  The court 1  endorsed this interpretation, concluding that "whether the claims are directed to subject matter within [section] 101 should not turn on whether the claimed subject matter does 'business' instead of something else."  105  While a limited amount of business method patents had been issued before,  the P T O  106  experienced a veritable boom in patent applications after State Street, especially for business methods performed over the Internet—so-called "e-commerce" patents.  107  The then-Commissioner of Patents  and Trademarks, Q . Todd Dickinson, confirmed that the Patent Office received 2,600 "business model" patent applications and granted 583 of these patents in the 12-month period between October  Id. at 1375-76. The court also pointed out that the Second Circuit in Hotel Security Checking v. Lorraine  Co. did  not rely on the business method exception,to invalidate the patent at issue in that case, but invalidated the patent because the invention lacked the requisite "novelty." Id. at 1376-77, citing MPEP 706.03(a) (1994); Examination Guidelines, 61 Fed. Reg. 7478 at 7479 (1996). Id.  Indeed, Signature Financial got one. In late 1998, one source reckoned that despite the business methods exception, there may have been over 2,000 patents for financial products already in existence. Jaret Seiberg, "Docket: Ruling Threatens Banks with Patent Lawsuits" American Banker (2 September 1998) at 3. Another source estimated in 1999 that more than 1,000 patents had been issued for software-based inventions in the areas of business management, finance and accounting. Paul. A. Beck, "State Street Bank Case Causes Shock Waves in Banking and Financial Industry" (1999) 147 Pitts. L.J. 7 at 9. See Tony V. Pezzano, "State Street Court Case Opens News World for Tech Patents" American Banker (18 January 1999) at 2. State Street's ringing endorsement of software patents caused a boom is computer-related patents generally—during 1999 it was reported that there had been a 45% increase in approvals for data processing and computer related inventions, and numerous sources report a drastic increase in the number of applications: John T. Acquino, "Patently Permissive: PTO Filings Up After Ruling Expands Protection for Business and Net Software" (1999) 85 A.B.A.J. 30.  39  Part III. Concerning the Effects on Innovation  1998 and September 1999.  108  1 The most notorious of these was U.S. Patent No. 5,794,207, entitled  "Method and Apparatus for a Cryptographically Assisted Commercial Network System Designed to Facilitate Buyer-Driven Purchase Offers."  Issued less than one month after State Street to  Priceline.com, the patent protects that company's on-line reverse-auction bidding system, whereby you can "name your own price" on airline tickets, home mortgages, hotel rooms, and automobiles.  109  Upon receiving the patent, the Priceline's Chairman and Chief Executive Officer, Jay Walker, trumpeted that e-commerce patents are a tremendously positive next step for all U.S. companies involved in creating Internet-based applications. ... Traditionally, patents have been the bedrock on which inventors built long-term, thriving businesses. E-commerce is no-exception. The PTO's actions support our nation's policy that cyberspace innovators should be encouraged and rewarded for advancing America's lead in Internetbased applications.  110  :  ;  Others, including a reader of Forbes magazine, were less enthusiastic: "Cool! Jay Walker has apparently patented the 'business method' known as a Dutch auction—a method by which the U.S. Treasury sells hundreds of billions of dollars' worth of securities each year."  111  This comment  highlights the main criticism of business method patents—that the use of a computer to implement well known business practices on the Internet is obvious and should not result in a patent grant.  108  W. Scott Petty, "Business Model Patents: Here Today, Gone Tomorrow?" Intel/. Prop. Today (May 2000) at 40. In 1997, only 31 pure business-method patents had been granted. William C. Smith, "Patent This!" (March 2001) 87 A.B.A.J. 49 at 51.  109  Peter H. Lewis, "Web Concern Gets Patent for its Model of Business" N. Y. Times(\ 1 August 1998) at D l . Two other patents protecting Internet technology received attention at about the same time: CyberGold, for its method of paying consumers to look at advertisements on the Internet, and NetDelivery, for its electronic delivery management ("EDM") technology. Id.  110  Don Sussis, "Autumn Signals A Harvest of Opportunity On (and Off) the Net" Silicon Alley Reporter (October 1998) at 88.  1,1  Byron L. Winn, "Readers Say" Forbes(31 May 1999) at 18.  112  James Gleick, "Patently Absurd" A^. Y. Times (12 March 2000 ) at 6-44. Lawrence Lessig, "Online Patents: Leave Them Pending" Wall St. Journal (Ii March 2000) at A22. Tim Watts, "The E-boom Causes A Troubling Test Of Patents" Business Review Weekly (5 May 2000) at 42.  112  Part III. Concerning  40  the Effects on Innovation  Rather than fostering innovation, claimed critics, business model patents stifle creativity and represent an improper grant of a monopoly within the open framework of the Internet. Even more troubling, companies were litigating these patents very aggressively.  In October  1999, Pricelihe sued Microsoft for using a reverse-auction method on its Expedia travel site, asserting that it turned over confidential and technical data to Microsoft during an eight-month period when the companies were negotiating a strategic partnership.  113  Under a January 2000 settlement, Expedia was  allowed to continue its price-matching service if it agreed to pay a royalty to Priceline.  114  Amazon.com also made headlines in October 1999 with its patent infringement suit againstBarnes & Noble. On September 28, Amazon.com founder and C E O Jeff Bezos had received a patent for Amazon's "1 - Click" ordering system, whereby a customer who has already given his or his pertinent ordering information (i.e., name, address, and credit card number) is able to purchase an item over the Internet with a single "click" of the mouse button.  115  As the Christmas shopping season approached,  Barnesandnoble.com, the website for Barnes & Noble, began offering an "Express Lane" one-click ordering service much like Amazon's. A suit was filed, and after a five-day hearing the Federal District Court for the Western District of Washington issued an injunction barring Barnesandnoble.com from  113  Priceline asked the court to award both actual and punitive damages as well as a permanent injunction based on patent infringement and state unfair practice claims. Del Jones, "Businesses Battle over Intellectual Property: Courts Choked with Lawsuits to Protect Ideas—And Profits" USA Today {2 August 2000) at IB. According to Jay Walker, when the deal fell through, Microsoft Chairman Bill Gates said that "many companies were suing Microsoft for patent infringement and that Microsoft had no intention of allowing patent rights to stand in its way," and that "Priceline could, in effect, get in line." For its part, Microsoft denied receiving any confidential information and publicly reiterated its strong belief in information protection. Id.  114  See Smith, supra note 108.  115  U.S. Patent No. 5,960,411, "Method and System for Placing a Purchase Order Via a Communications Network." According to Bezos, who was voted Time's Man of the Year for 1999, the invention was designed to facilitate online purchasing by overcoming a customer's tendency to abandon "shopping carts" prior to checkout. See Noel D. Humphreys, "Patent Protection: Encouraging or Discouraging Innovation?" (2000) 22 Pennsylvania  Lawyer SA.  This author submits, however, that such a one-click system probably surprises shoppers into inadvertent purchases. Amazon won another controversial method patent in February of 2000, Patent No. 6,029,141, which protects its "affiliate" system that lets websites collect a cut of sales when they refer a customer to another site. Id.  Part UI.  Concerning  41  the Effects on Innovation  offering the one-click feature pending outcome of the suit."  6  In her decision, Judge Pechman invoked  a variety of the traditional justifications for intellectual property rights: The public is served by innovation on the Internet and in electronic commerce, particularly now while it is still developing rapidly.  Competition to provide unique, effective and enjoyable consumer  experiences will lead to innovation and diversity in on-line commerce. On the other hand, innovation will be discouraged if competitors are permitted a free ride on each other's patented inventions. Protection of intellectual property rights in innovations will foster greater competition and innovation. ... The public has a strong interest in the enforcement of intellectual property rights. The purpose of the patent system is to reward inventors and provide incentives for further innovation by preventing others from exploiting their work. Encouraging Amazon.com to continue to innovate—and forcing competitors to come up with their own new ideas—unquestionably best serves the public interest."  7  With only weeks until Christmas, Barnesandnoble.com was forced to design around Amazon.corn's patent by creating a "double-click" ordering system in which two clicks of the mouse were required instead of one. The  case caused a firestorm of controversy, fanned in large part by maverick Internet  entrepreneur Tim O'Reilly, president of computer book publisher O'Reilly & Associates, Inc."  8  O'Reilly was joined in his cause by MacArthur "genius" grant winner Richard Stallman, an ardent foe of software patents and founder of the Boston-based Free Software Foundation.  Stallman was so  disgusted with Amazon.com that he called for a boycott of the Internet bookseller. Although O'Reilly stopped short of supporting the boycott, he did encourage each visitor to his Web site to contact Jeff  1 , 6  Amazon.com  117  v. Barnesandnoble.com,  Id. at 1248-49.  73 F. Supp. 2d 1228 (W.D. Wash. 1999).  ns "yjjg f _ heeling development environment that has given us both the Internet and open source tools ... has rcc  w  demonstrated convincingly that there is enormous power in an open, shared platform where ideas are given away as the foundation for further innovations," O'Reilly said. "So far, entrepreneurs, stock market investors, and computer users have all benefited enormously from the open, non-proprietary approach historically used for developing Internet technologies." Bleys W. Rose, "Patent debate hot topic on web" The Press [Santa Rosa, CA] (10 March 2000) at E l .  Democrat  42  Part III. Concerning the Effects on Innovation  Bezos with concerns about the Amazon patent. responded.  Within a day or two, more than 10,000 had  119  Surprisingly, after participating in an online conversation with O'Reilly, Bezos started criticizing the patent system himself.  In a three-page reform proposal posted on the Amazon.com  website, Bezos agreed that "meaningful (perhaps radical) patent reform" was needed. "I now believe," he said, that "it's possible that the current rules governing business method and software patents could end up harming all of us."  120  Among his suggestions for restructuring the patent system was a reduction  of the patent term—now 20 years from the time of application—to three to live years for software and business-method patents, and the introduction of a one-month public comment period before a patent could issue.  121  Despite all this, the "1-Click" litigation led to an array of new lawsuits and encouraged hundreds of U.S. companies to apply to patent their Web site features. In a move that caused another uproar from the tech community, British Telecom announced in June 2000 that it would consider enforcing its patent for "hyperlinking," the method by which certain words or phrases can be crossreferenced with the click of a button.  122  On August 9, Mercata announced that it had been issued a  patent for its group-buying technology, and that it was going "to probe for possible infringements by competitors."  123  Similarly, on August 28, DE Technologies announced that it was about to be issued a  broad patent covering "a process for carrying out an international transaction ... using computer-to-  "  9  Victoria Slind-Flor, "Bar reacts to Bezos patent reform plan: Adopting his changes would upset good system, they say" The National Law Journal (21 March 2000).  120  R. Scott MacKendrick, "Amazon 1 -Click decision—relief or invitation to litigate?" The Lawyer's Weekly (13 April 2001).  121  Slind-Flor, supra note 119. Bezos even suggested that the shorter term for business-method patents be applied retroactively, to his own patents as well. I'll discuss the merits of this reform in Section V.B.2, infra.  122  SeeAndrewJ. Frackman & Robert M. Stern, "An update from the patent wars" New York Law Journal (29 November 2000) at 1.  123  See "Mercata Wins Patent on Buying Technology" N. Y. Times (9 August 2000). Such a broad business method patent conceivably could prevent any company from offering a group-buying Internet service.  Part III. Concerning the Effects on Innovation  43  computer communication" and that it was embarking on a program of enforcement against any company conducting international trade transactions over the Internet.  124  Other, less-publicized patents were also causing a stir. After State Street, it seemed that you could get a patent on a method of doing practically anything, no matter how trivial. Inventor Edward Pechter of Valencia, Calif., for example, was granted a patent for a "method of bra size determination by direct measurement of the breast."  125  In pertinent part, Pechter's pectoral procedure gauges cup  size "by directly measuring with the tape the circumference of each unclothed breast from the beginning of the breast mound at one side laterally to the parasternal area medially." On 30 November i  1999, Kevin and George Repper were granted patent number 5,993,336 for a method of swinging a tennis racquet. As described in the abstract, their technique consists of wearing kneepads and swatting the ball "either while the covered knee is on the tennis court surface or just prior to the knee contacting the tennis court surface."  This "innovation," the patent claim concludes, "enables a player to  successfully return balls that otherwise are out of effective stroking reach." Even before State Street, though, the PTO was issuing very curious patents.  In 1995, for  example, after finding that "cats are not characteristically disposed toward voluntary aerobic exercise," Kevin Amiss and Martin Abbot of Virginia patented a "method for inducing cats to exercise [by flashing a laser beam] onto the floor or wall or other opaque surface in the vicinity of the cat, then moving the laser so as to cause the bright pattern of light to move in an irregular way fascinating to cats and to any other animal with a chase instinct."  126  Since April Fools' Day 1997, Dale D. Miller has had the rights to  Patent No. 5,616,089, covering a "putting method in which the golfer controls the speed of the putt  See William M. Bulkeley, "A Billion-Dollar Patent?: Software Developer Seeking To Protect Process Using Internet For Foreign Trade" Wall St. Journal(28 August 2000) at Bl; "Patent Application Could Evolve into Trouble for ECommerce" Wall St. Journal (li August 2000) at B l . U.S. Patent No. 5,965,809 (12 October 1999). U.S. Patent No. 5,443,036 (22 August 1995).  Part III.  Concerning  44  the Effects on Innovation  and the direction of the putt primarily with the golfer's dominant throwing hand, yet uses the golfer's nondominant hand to maintain the blade of the putter stable." And consider the following claim: A method for remodeling an existing building, said method comprising: cataloging design ideas that utilize predetermined building products; presenting the design ideas to a client; allowing the client to select a design idea...; [and] preparing a visual image ... representing the building remodeled with the design idea selected by the client.  127  Wholly divorced from particular artifacts, it broadly appropriates an architectural services technique.  128  Or consider Patent No. 5,761,857, which was recently issued to two architects for their configuration of residential housing. In place of a traditional hallway connecting the several rooms and apartments, the patentees came up with the ground-breaking idea of applying staircases external to the structure. Other patents are troubling for different reasons.  129  Patent No. 6,025,810, issued in February:  2000, is for an antenna that sends signals faster than the speed of light—an impossible feat, if you believe decades of science based on Einstein's theory of relativity.  130  Similarly impossible is Patent No.  5,533,051, issued in 1996, which covers a technique that purports to compress any data set by at least one bit without loss of information—a process that, if done recursively, could shrink the Encyclopedia Britannica to a single word from which the original could be flawlessly reconstructed.  131  More worrisome than the issuance of such trivial and ridiculous patents is the effect that the new patents will have on the business environment in general.  As pointed out by Leo Raskind,  Professor of Law at Brooklyn University, business method patents were "thrust into a vibrant, established process of competitive commercial rivalry, a process that has traditionally been governed by emulation and by customary practices. An added perverse result of this intrusion is the incentive for  127  U.S. Patent No. 5,668,736 (16 September 1997).  128  Thomas, supra note 97, at 30-31.  125  See Teresa Riordan, "Architects Debate Concepts Behind Housing Design" N. Y. Times (19 July 1999) at C l 1.  130  Sec Philip E. Ross, "Patently Absurd Technology and gamesmanship has overwhelmed the U.S. Patent Office. How to fix it?" Forbes (29 May 2000) at 180.  131  Id.  Part III. Concerning  the Effects on  Innovation  4S  some entrepreneurs to become collectors of patent royalties, rather than to continue as active participants in the marketplace. If the boom in business method patents continues at its accelerating pace, the so-called superhighway of electronic commerce could be partially converted into a toll road/'  132  Leo J. Raskind, ""The State Street Bank Decision: The Bad Business of Unlimited Patent Protection for Methods of Doing Business" (1999) 10 Fordham L P , Media & Ent. L.J. 61 at 66.  Part IV. Identifying  IV.  the Issues  46  I D E N T I F Y I N G T H E ISSUES  We've looked at the evidence from the various industries of the new economy, but it would be useful to now organize the problems along issue lines. What exactly are the issues facing the patent system, and in what areas are the problems most critical? Before we do that, however, we should step back and review the theory behind the patent system, and how it is intended to foster innovation.  A.  Patent Theory  The origin of the United States patent system dates back to birth of the nation itself. Drafted in 1787, Article I, Section 8, Clause 8 of the U.S. Constitution authorizes the creation of both the patent system and the copyright system: The Congress shall have Power . . . To promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries.  133  The language of the clause hints at the two main philosophical justifications for granting patent and copyright monopolies—natural rights theory and utilitarianism. Generally attributable to the writings of John Locke, the theory of natural rights holds that individuals have an inherent right to the fruits of  Art. I, § 8, cl. 8. While contained in a single clause, the Patent and Copyright Clause of the U.S. Constitution is commonly treated as two distinct provisions, each with a distinct grant of authority and distinct subject matter: (a)  For Patents: "The Congress shall have Power ... To promote the Progress of ... useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to ... Inventors the exclusive Right to their ... Discoveries."  (b)  For Copyrights: "The Congress shall have Power ... To promote the Progress of Science..., by securing for limited Times to Authors ... the exclusive Right to their ... Writings..."  See also Donald S. Chisum, Chisum on Patents(1998) at GI-23: '"Useful Arts' is synonymous with the contemporary concept of technological arts and is contrasted with 'Science' the promotion of which is the object of the copyright system."  47  Part IV. Identifying  the Issues  their labour.  Like other systems of property rights, an intellectual property system should protect  134  individual rights to inventions so that others cannot appropriate them.  Utilitarianism, on the other  hand, proposes that the main justification for the grant of monopoly is a matter of public welfare. By promoting scientific progress, intellectual property systems serve all of society.  135  In analyzing exactly how the patent system fosters innovation, traditional economic theory has emphasized the incentive function of patents.  136  It usually costs more, in terms of effort and money, to  discover something new than it does to duplicate someone else's discovery. Inventors may work on their discoveries for a variety of reasons, but so long as one of the motivations is the prospect of financial reward, inventors will be concerned about the possibility that others will imitate their discoveries. If an invention can be imitated quickly, the inventor will soon be forced to compete with those who did not incur the development costs that he did. This competition will reduce, or even eliminate, the profits an inventor can earn from his discovery, and so he may decide not to pursue it. By providing a temporary monopoly under which an inventor can recoup his initial expenditures, patents therefore provide an important incentive to engage in innovative activity.  John Locke, Second Treatise of Government  (1698). Adam Smith also strongly asserted the property right of an  individual to his labour: "The property which every man has in his own labour, as it is the original foundation of all other property, so it is the most sacred and inviolable." Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Book 1, Chapter 1 (1776). While the two theories seem inherently opposed, the Framers of the Constitution saw little conflict. In the one comment regarding the intellectual property clause, James Madison appears to reconcile both justifications: "The utility of this power will scarcely be questioned. The copyright of authors have been solemnly adjudged in Great Britain to be a right of common law. The right to useful inventions seems with equal reason to belong to the inventors. The public good fully coincides in both cases with the claims of individuals." The Federalist No. 43 (Clinton Rossiter ed, 1961) at 271-72 . See also John Shepard Wiley, Jr., "Copyright at the School of Patent" (1991) 58 U. Chi. L. Rev. 119 at 140—contending that the labour-desert theory and utilitarian perspective "tend to converge as a practical matter, because law governing innovation policy usually must treat creators fairly in order to give them the incentives to act in ways that benefit consumers." Nevertheless, the tension between the rights of the individual and the public good has animated the copyright and patent debates ever since. See Frederic M. Scherer, IndustrialMarket  Structure andEconomic  Performance  (Rand McNally, 1970) at 379-99;  John S. McGee, "Patent Exploitation: Some Economic and Legal Problems" (1966) 9 J. L. & Econ. 135; Dan Usher, "The Welfare Economics of Invention" (1964) 31 Economica 279; Richard R. Nelson, "The Economics of Invention: A Survey of the Literature" (1959) 32 J. Bus. 101.  Part IV. Identifying  48  the Issues  Thus, in the words of the U.S. Supreme Court, the patent laws were enacted to promote innovation by offering a limited right of exclusion "as an incentive to inventors to risk the often enormous costs in terms of time, research and development."  137  Congress intended that "the  productive effort thereby fostered [would] have a positive effect on society through the introduction of new products and processes of manufacture into the economy, and the emanations by way of increased employment and better lives for our citizens."  138  Economists have identified three main ways in which society benefits from the grant of patent rights.  139  First, patent ownership enables a successful inventor to recoup sunk research costs, thereby,  providing incentives for the initial investment in discovering the invention. Second, by allowing the owner of a new invention to exclude the "free-riders" who did not bear the costs of invention, patents encourage the inventor to develop that invention commercially. Finally, by requiring that an inventor publicly disclose the inner workings of his invention, patents foster the diffusion of new technology, and may lead to other inventions from competitors attempting to invent around the patent.  140  Yet while it provides substantial benefits, the patent system also creates significant costs. Foremost among these are the output restrictions and correspondingly higher prices associated with monopolization. Since patent holders have a monopoly over the patented technology, they can charge a higher price than they could in a competitive market. In most cases, there will be some consumers  Kewanee  Oil Co. v. Bicron Corp.,  416 U.S. 470 at 480 (1974).  Id.  Sec Scherer, supra note 136, at 380: "Governments have elected to grant exclusive patent rights on inventions for three main reasons: to promote invention, to encourage the development and commercial utilization of inventions, and to encourage inventors to disclose their inventions to the public." The three different benefits have been called the "incentive to invent" theory, the "incentive to innovate" theory (innovation being the development of an invention into commercial form), and the "incentive to disclosure" theory. See Rebecca S. Eisenberg, "Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights and Experimental Use" (1989) 56 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1017. Again, in the words of the Supreme Court, "such additions to the general store of knowledge are of such importance to the public weal that the Federal Government is willing to pay the high price of seventeen years of exclusive use for its disclosure, which disclosure, it is assumed, will stimulate ideas and the eventual development of further significant advances." Kewanee  Oil, supra note 137, at 481. Not only does disclosure promote greater  knowledge, it eliminates secrecy which might lead to wasteful duplicative research. See Martin J. Adelman, "Property Rights Theory and Patent Antitrust: The Role of Compulsory Licensing" (1977) 52 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 977.  Part IV. Identifying  49  the Issues  willing to buy the product at the competitive price, but unwilling to pay the higher price charged by the patent holder.  141  Other inefficiencies may result from distortions of economic activity.  Patents may force  competitors to waste time and effort finding redundant solutions to a problem that has already been solved.  142  Competing firms hoping to make patentable inventions ahead of their rivals may spend too  much money trying to develop inventions quickly, when the same result could be achieved at lower social cost through a less accelerated research effort.  143  Companies may also divert resources from  research in fields where patent protection is weak or unavailable to research in areas that are more likely to yield profitable patent monopolies.  144  Thus, under the traditional incentive theory—also called the "reward theory"—patents are viewed as a classic tradeoff between the benefits of greater innovation and the costs of monopoly power.  Later economic theory, however, has proposed that monopolies are actually conducive to  innovation, and look at the patent model slightly differently. In the 1930s, Joseph Schumpeter argued that in a dynamic model of the capitalist system, monopoly conditions may promote innovation and growth more effectively than competition.  145  He reasoned that in the rapidly-changing conditions of a capitalist economy, investment in innovation  141  The negative impact of monopoly power was forefront in the mind of the author of the original Patent Act. Thomas Jefferson, like other Americans, had an instinctive aversion to monopolies. After all, it was a monopoly on tea that sparked the Revolution and Jefferson did not favor an equivalent form of monopoly under the new government. His abhorrence of monopoly extended initially to patents as well. From France, he wrote to James Madison in July 1788 urging a Bill of Rights provision restricting monopoly, and against the argument that limited monopoly might serve to incite "ingenuity," he argued forcefully that "the benefit even of limited monopolies is too doubtful to be opposed to that of their general suppression." He subsequently modified his position, authored the Patent Act of 1793, and directed the patent board for several years. See Thomas P. Burke, "Software Patent Protection: Debugging the Current System" (1994) 69 Notre Dame L. Rev. 1115 at 1130.  142  143  See Donald F. Turner, "The Patent System and Competitive Policy" (1969) 44 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 449 at 455. See Richard Posner, Economic  Analysis of Law (Little, Brown, 1977) at 54 ; Yoram Barzel, "The Optimal Timing  of Innovations" (1968) 50 Rev. Econ. & Stat. 348. 144  See Fritz Machlup, "An Economic Review of the Patent System," Subcomm. on Patents, Trademarks, and Copyrights of the Senate Comm. on the Judiciary, Study No. 15, 85th Cong, 2d Sess. (GPO, 1958) at 45-50.  143  Joseph Schumpeter, Capitalism,  Socialism and Democracy  (Harper & Row 3d ed, 1950) at 87-106.  Part IV. Identifying  SO  the Issues  requires some sort of hedge against losses. Protection from competition also allows firms "to gain the time and space for further developments."  146  Finally, and perhaps most important, the prospect of  earning more than an ordinary return permits innovators to secure the financial backing of capitalists and to bid productive resources away from their current uses.  147  A monopoly position secured through  patent protection thus may increase rather than restrict the use of known technologies by facilitating the commercial introduction of such technologies by innovating firms. In the 1970s, Edmund Kitch built on Schumpeter's work to develop what he called the "prospect theory" of patent protection.  148  Kitch argued that granting broad patent rights in the early  stages of innovation promotes efficiency in the further development of promising technological prospects, much like the award of exclusive mineral claims promotes efficiency in the exploration of natural resources. In his view, a new process or apparatus would more likely be commercialized by the inventor who had broad patent protection by insulating such patentee from competitive rivalry during the early stages of the commercial development of new technology. It would also allow the inventor to better coordinate its activities with those of potential imitators to reduce inefficient duplication of inventive effort.  Broadest scope, said Kitch, should be afforded to "pioneer patents"—those patents  which represented important advances and offered the greatest prospect of generating significant ancillary technology. Though many economists were skeptical of Kitch's prospect theory of patents,  149  it appears to  have influenced the policy debate at the time, lending credence to Congress' new mandate to better  Id. at 89. '  Joseph Schumpeter, The Theory of Economic Development  (Transaction reprint, 1983) at 67-74 .  Edmund W. Kitch, "The Nature and Function of the Patent System" (1977) 20 J. L. & Econ. 265. The term "prospect theory" highlighted the analogy between the functions of patent monopolies and awards of exclusive mineral claims in government-owned lands in the American West. See Scherer, supra note 54, at 9-10; F.M. Scherer, Industrial Market Structure and Economic  Performance  (Rand  McNally, 2d ed. 1980) at 447 n.30—stating that Kitch's views seem "little influenced by any concern for reality." Kitch's views depend at least in part on an empirical assumption that many inventors acquire patent protection far in advance of the appearance of any commercial product. Empirical evidence contradicts Kitch on this point,  51  Part IV. Iden tifying the Issues  exploit the fruits of basic research, and giving additional support for the strengthening the patent rights that occurred in the 1980s. In particular, it has been suggested that a tacit endorsement of the prospect theory of patents by the Federal Circuit led to its reduction of patentability standards and elevation of patent validity—making patents stronger and easier to get.  B.  150  Patent Scope  Patent scope, is the basic measurement of the value of the patent right. At the most general level, patent scope—sometimes also referred to a patent breadth—can be described as the region of technology space from which a patentee may exclude others from operating. Clearly, the broader the patent is, the more valuable it is.  It seems logical, therefore, that a patent system which confers  broader scope makes inventions more valuable, and thereby provides greater innovation incentives. The problem, of course, is that a researcher has to worry about producing an invention that will be judged to infringe someone else's patent.  A system which allows broader patents makes this more  likely, and therefore makes research riskier and less valuable.  151  Due to this tension, analysis of the consequences of patent scope involves more than just the classic tradeoff between the objective of encouraging innovation at the cost of creating monopoly power. The rate of innovation does not necessarily increase as patent scope increases, because of the constraints that possible infringement places on an inventor's expectation of return.  however. Barkev Sanders, in a study of assigned patents issued in 1938, 1948, and 1952, found that of the estimated 10 percent of patented inventions ever put to commercial use, about 40 percent were first put to use before the patent application was filed, about 50 percent were first put to use while the application was pending, and only about 10 percent were first put to use after issuance of the patent. Barkev Sanders, "Speedy Entry of Patented Inventions into Commercial Use" (1962) 6 Pat., Trademark & Copyright J. of Research & Educ. 87. See Kevin Rhodes, "The Federal Circuit's Patent Nonobviousness Standards: Theoretical Perspectives on Recent Doctrinal Changes" (1991) 85 Nw. U.L. Rev. 1051. The infringing inventor may still be able to practice his invention by securing a license from the holder of the socalled "blocking patent"—but that, of course, increases costs.  Part IV. Identifying  1.  52  the Issues  THEORETICAL ANALYSES OF PATENT SCOPE  It is useful to distinguish between three types of patent scope issues, based on the relationship between a patented invention and others which might infringe it. The first situation is where the potentially infringing invention is developed independently of the patented invention. The second situation is that of "cumulative invention," in which the potentially infringing invention builds upon the patented invention.  The third situation is that of inventions which are research tools, used primarily for the  specific purpose of developing other inventions. In the traditional context of independent, non-cumulative inventions, the issue of patent scope is viewed in terms of the tradeoff between providing monopoly profits to the inventor to stimulate innovation versus the losses in market efficiency resulting from that monopoly power.  152  This tradeoff  is similar to the one associated with granting a certain duration of patent protection, and thus the problem is to choose a combination of breadth and duration that minimizes welfare loss while still providing an adequate level of innovation incentive.  153  Within this framework, a generalized increase  in patent breadth or scope, although it may result in decreased efficiencies due to increased monopoly power, unambiguously increases the rate of innovation because it does not affect the incentives of subsequent, potentially infringing inventors—inventions are completely independent. The case of non-independent, cumulative invention—in which subsequent inventors stand metaphorically on the shoulders of the giants who came before them—has received considerable theoretical attention as of late.  152  154  Edmund Kitch viewed this is a problem of optimal coordination  See M. Waterson, "The Economics of Product Patents" (1990) 80 Amer. Econ. Rev. 860; Paul Klemperer, "How Broad Should the Scope of Patent Protection Be?" (1990) 21 Rand J. of Econ. 113.  153  See Richard Gilbert & Carl Shapiro, "Optimum Patent Length and Breadth" (1990) 21 Rand J. of Econ. 106.  154  See Suzanne Scotchmer, "Standing on the Shoulder of Giants: Cumulative Innovation and the Patent Law" (1991) S J. of Econ. Persp. 29; Jerry Green & Suzanne Scotchmer, "On the Division of Profit in Sequential Innovation" (1995) 26 Rand J. of Econ. 20; Howard F. Chang, "Patent Scope, Antitrust Policy, and Cumulative Invention"  Part IV. Identifying  S3  the Issues  among different researchers working on related technologies.  1SS  In the absence of coordination, there  will be a wasteful duplication of effort, and possibly over-investment of research and development resources, as firms seek to beat each other to important results. As discussed above, Kitch proposed to grant broad patent rights to a pioneering inventor early in the development of a line of technology would ensure a more orderly development of that technology. To the extent that other inventors have ideas or capabilities that contribute to the advancement of the technology, the pioneering inventor would have an incentive to include them in the development, via cross-licensing or other contractual arrangements. Later work on cumulative invention incorporated the incentives of the potential follow-on inventors into the economic models. For researchers such as O'Donoghue, Scotchmer and Green, the question of scope can be characterized in terms of the magnitude of the improvement that an invention must represent before it will be granted a patent of its own, and/or held to infringe the patent of a previous inventor.  156  Their line of research accorded with Kitch's view that broad patent protection  should be afforded to the initial invention in a cumulative development line. Scotchmer even proposes that "second-generation" products should not be patentable at all.  157  If the first and second innovators,'.  she argues, can negotiate the terms of a licensing agreement before the second inventor sinks any of itsresearch investments, the first inventor will have the incentive to license its technology to the.second whenever it is optimal to do so, under terms that do not prevent the development of the second invention. Her approach, however, presumes that the trajectory of innovation is known in advance.  (199S) 26 Rand J. of Econ. 34; Ted O'Donoghue, "A Patentability Requirement for Sequential Innovation" (1998) 29 Rand J. of Econ. 654. The phrase "standing of the shoulders of giants" is generally attributable to Sir Isaac Newton. See Robert K. Merton, On The Shoulders of Giants (1965)—quoting a letter by Sir Isaac Newton. Kitch, supra note 148. O'Donoghue, supra note 154; Scotchmer & Green, supra note 154. Suzanne Scotchmer, "Protecting Early Innovators: Should Second-Generation Products Be Patentable?" (1996) 27 RandJ. of Econ. 322.  Part IV. Identifying  54  the Issues  As emphasized by evolutionary economics,  158  it is more often the case—particularly early in the  development of a new line of technology—that no one knows which directions of improvement are desirable, or even possible, and therefore such ex an te licensing would be unlikely.  159  More recently, Hopenhayn and Mitchell explored the implications of the fact that inventions differ in the extent to which they spawn "fertile" lines of subsequent inventions.  160  Ignoring the kinds  of ex ante agreements that Scotchmer uses to ensure that infringing second-generation products will still be developed, they show that broad patent scope is more costly for inventions that are more fertile, because it may inhibit subsequent developments.  On the other hand, it is important to provide  good incentives to develop such fertile inventions to begin with, because they are socially very, ;  valuable. Hopenhayn and Mitchell show that overall innovation incentives can be improved by offering  1  patentees a "menu" of combinations of patent duration and patent scope. Optimal construction of this menu induces patentees to reveal their private knowledge regarding fertility of their inventions, and thereby achieves a better balance between the incentives of the initial and subsequent inventors than; can be achieved with uniform patent scope. The authors suggest that a mechanism with properties such as theirs could be implemented by allowing patentees to choose different types of patents with differentdurations and legal rights.  161  The third patent scope situation, that of patented research tools, can be thought of as a special case of cumulative invention in which the initial invention in the sequence has no value except as a.  138  See Richard R. Nelson & Sidney Winter, An Evolutionary  Theory of Economic  Change (Harvard Univ. Press,  1982). . 139  In their historical review of U.S. industry, Merges and Nelson also show that ex ante licensing is unlikely and/or ineffective—see infra, notes 169-177 and accompanying text.  160  Hugo Hopenhayn & Matthew Mitchell, "Innovation Fertility and Patent Design" (1999) National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W7070.  161  As an example, they suggest that patentees might be required to accept shorter patent durations in order to receive protection against patent infringement under the doctrine of equivalents. Id. This approach presents difficulties, however—see infra, Section V.B.2.  Part IV. Identifying  55  the Issues  platform for future innovation.  162  Unlike the cumulative invention, the research tool does not typically  compete in the marketplace with the products developed using it, and therefore development of the downstream product does not reduce the profit stream of the research tool inventor. Indeed, if the patented tool has no direct commercial market, its owner can profit only to the extent it is used in the development of other inventions. This would seem to make the situation in some sense easier than that of cumulative invention, because the incentives of the research tool inventor and the research tool user are more in line with one another—they both want the downstream product to be manufactured and soldjthe only question is how much the inventor should receive in royalties. Schankerman and Scotchmer recently investigated the enforcement of patents for research tools from the perspective of maximizing the incentives to develop such tools.  163  They considered  whether it is necessary to grant the patentee the right to an injunction preventing the sale of products developed with the tool, or whether the availability of damages for patent infringement is sufficient. .• They showed that the current legal treatment of patent damages as a "reasonable royalty" is logically flawed, so that maximizing the incentive to develop research tools requires either that injunctions be available, or.that the damages rule be changed to award to the research tool patentee the profits earned by the infringer.  2.  164  EMPIRICAL STUDIES OF PATENT SCOPE  There has been relatively little empirical analysis of the effects of different degrees of patent scope, primarily because it is very difficult to measure patent scope in a systematic way across large numbers  162  See Scotchmer, supra note 157; Michael Heller & Rebecca Eisenberg, "Can Patents Deter Innovation? The Anticommons in Biomedical Research" Science (1 May 1998) at 698.  163  Mark Schankerman & Suzanne Scotchmer, "Damages and Injunctions in the Protection of Proprietary Research Tools" (1999) National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W7086.  164  I'll discuss research tools in more detail in Section V.D, infra.  Part IV. Identifying  56  the Issues  of patents, and because there are few natural experiments in which different degrees of patent scope can be observed. Josh Lerner has examined whether patents that appear to have relatively broad scope are more valuable to patentees that narrower ones.  Looking at biotechnology firms, whose values are closely  tied to their intellectual property, he found that firms whose patents span more International Patent Classes (IPCs) are valued more highly by venture capitalists.  165  While his finding does not directly  address the question of patent scope expansion, it provides threshold support for the underlying idea that broader scope increases value and therefore increases innovation incentives.  A more recent  German study by Harhoff, Scherer and Vopel, however, failed to find that the number of IPCs is related to patent value, as measured in survey responses by patent owners.  166  One of the few natural experiments on patent scope occurred in the late 1980s in Japan. Prior to 1988, the Japanese patent system essentially allowed only one claim per patent.  A complex  invention, or one with many distinct applications, had to be covered by many separate patents, all of which had to non-overlapping—a patentee would not be granted a patent whose claim covered any of the material of another patent, even if it was his own.  167  In 1988, Japan converted to a system much  like the U.S. system, in which a single patent can have multiple, overlapping claims. In their study of the Japanese reforms, Sakakibara and Branstetter argue, based on discussions with Japanese companies and patent experts, that in many cases it is not possible to protect a complicated invention using a series of independent claims. Even the most complete set of independent claims leaves "holes" in technology space that can only be covered with overlapping claims. Therefore, the change to a multi-claim system effectively increased patent scope by permitting more effective protection of these inventions.  165  Josh Lerner, "The Importance of Patent Scope: An Empirical Analysis" (1994) 25 Rand J. of Econ. 319.  166  Dietmar Harhoff, F.M. Scherer & Katrin Vogel, "Citations, Family Size, Opposition and the Value of Patent Rights—Evidence from Germany" (1999) National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W7108.  167  The non-overlapping nature of the pre-1988 Japanese system caused it to be referred to as the "sashimi" system, in reference to the thinly-sliced sushi dish. Mariko Sakakibara & Lee Branstetter, "Do Stronger Patents Induce More Innovation? Evidence from the 1988 Japanese Patent Law Reforms" (1999) NBER Working Paper No. W7066.  Part IV. Identifying  57  the Issues  Sakakibara and Branstetter hypothesize, based on the standard innovation incentive model, that such an increase in patent scope would increase the return to inventive activity, an effect-which should be observable in two ways. First, research and development spending by Japanese firms should have risen. Second, Japanese firms should have produced more inventions, and since the incentives created by the U.S. patent system did not change in 1988, this should have lead to an increase in patenting by Japanese firms in the U.S. The data, however, shows that neither of these occurred.  Although the late 1980s were a  period in which both Japanese R&D and Japanese patenting in the U.S. were rising, there was no measurable increase in their rates of growth around the time the policy change occurred.  168  It is  possible that despite the impression of the managers interviewed for the study, the ability to file overlapping claims does not result in a significant increase in patent scope, or that there was an effect, but that it was too difficult to see in data series that are changing rapidly for other reasons. Otherwise, their results suggest that changes in patent scope do not have significant effects on research incentives. The role of patent scope in fostering innovation in the United States has been examined in detail by Robert Merges and Richard Nelson.  169  Their evidence is not statistical, but rather an  . investigation: of the development of several historically-important technologies, and whether, as asserted by Kitch, affording broad patent protection to the "pioneer" innovators is in fact desirable. In the case of the electric lighting industry, Merges and Nelson found that Edison's dominant patent on the carbon filament as a light source did not result in rapid commercial development, and conclude that "the validation of Edison's broad patent slowed considerably."  170  168  the pace  of improvements  They also point out that the acquisition of Edison's patent enabled General Electric to  Sakakibara and Branstetter did find, however, an increase in Japanese R&D spending in the early 1980s. Id. Thus, just as in the United States, the increase in R&D spending preceded rather than followed the change in patent policy, and therefore cannot be considered a result of the policy change. See supra note 49 and accompanying text.  169  170  Robert P. Merges & Richard R. Nelson, "On the Complex Economics of Patent Scope" (1990) 90 Colum. L. Rev. 839. Id. at 886.  Part IV. Identifying  58  the Issues  obtain injunctions shutting down competitors, thereby increasing its market share from 40 to 75 percent.  General Electric then used its market dominance to limit entry into the industry, .while  making just minimal improvements to the light bulb.  Merges and Nelson contrast the rate of  technological improvement in electric lamps with the more rapid rate of development in other sectors of the electric industry, such as power generation and arc-lighting, where they found a causal relation between the absence of broad patent protection and the rapid entry of competing firms and accelerated product improvement.  171  The authors then turn to the automobile and airplane industries, which, like electric lighting, were also marked by dominant patents at their.inception.  The Selden patent on the light-weight  internal combustion engine and the Wright patent on the steering and stabilization system of aircraft contained broadly drawn claims covering a variety of embodiments. Again, Merges and Nelson found that these industries did not conform to the theoretical prediction that the dominant patentee would \ consider broad patent protection as an incentive to develop the subject matter. To the contrary, rather than commercializing his patent, Selden sought only to license the technology and collect royalties.  The automobile industry then developed through the efforts of  manufacturers who paid royalties to his licensing entity.  The Wrights, on the other hand, did  undertake to produce airplanes and to improve their design, but they refused to license others whose design ideas were at odds with theirs. Even worse, both parties further impeded technological process by engaging in extensive litigation against companies that did not recognize their patents.  172  The problems caused by the Selden and Wright patents were compounded when different companies finally managed to patent improvements on their designs. The existence of additional broad patents on complementary technologies meant that different companies could block each other from using key components.  Id. at 887.  In fact, the situation in the aeronautics industry during World War I was so  Part IV. Identifying  59  the Issues  serious that the Secretary of the Navy had to intervene with the establishment of an automatic crosslicensing arrangement.  173  Merges and Nelson cite the radio industry as a further example of the potential for gridlock in the development of a technology. In that industry, Marconi had acquired the patent rights to the basic two-element vacuum tube, or diode, while AT&T had acquired the fundamental patents on the triode vacuum tube. But because Marconi's diode patent was held to dominate AT&T's triode, and neither party would license the other, no one could commercialize the admittedly revolutionary triode. The conflict was ultimately resolved by the formation of a single entity, the Radio Corporation of America (RCA), which took in the owners of all of the potentially blocking patents as major shareholders in the 174  corporation. • < •  ..  • • ,  The development of the semiconductor and computer industries might have been similarly impeded but for a fortunate sequence of circumstances. The first involved AT&T's initial patent rights on the transistor. Although they were also broad enough to have given their holder control over a large "prospect," AT&T was barred,by an antitrust decree from enforcing them. The second instance, involved the parallel inventions of the integrated circuit (by Texas Instruments) and the Planar process for producing them cheaply (by Fairchild Instruments). Both of these companies obtained patents on their own inventions, which meant that each had to license the other to produce integrated circuits • effectively.  Fortunately, the Department of Defense was the principle purchaser of semiconductors at  the time and had a strong interest in seeing these important technologies become broadly available throughout the industry. As a result, the government quickly stepped in to impose a cross-licensing arrangement on the companies.  172  173  174  175  Id. at 888-89. Id. at 891.  Several other companies had important patent positions in radio, including General Electric and Westinghouse. Id. at 892. Id. at 894.  ,  Part IV. Identifying  the Issues  60  Computer technology also benefited from the lack of broad initial patents.  Although  pioneering inventors Eckert and Mauchley did file for and receive a patent on their ENIAC computer design, the patent was ruled invalid because of a judgment that the prior art included much of what they claimed. Since this ruling, Merges and Nelson find, patents have played only a very minor role in the computer industry, and where patents are concerned, cross licensing is common. As a result, the pace of technical change has been rapid.  176  Based on their review of these and other industries, including chemical and biotechnological, the authors state their conclusion as to the effects of broad patent protection as follows: Our, general conclusion is that multiple and competitive sources of invention are socially preferable to a structure where there is only one or a few sources.  Public policy, including patent law, ought to  encourage inventive rivalry, and not hinder it. ... [A] rivalrous structure surely has its inefficiencies. But such a structure does tend to generate rapid technological progress and seems a better social bet than a regime where only one or a few organizations control the development of a given technology.  177  Thus, the' findings of Merges and Nelson, while not definitive, seriously question theconclusion of Kitch—and implicitly, the later work of Scotchmer, Green, O'Donoghue and others— that strong property rights for pioneering inventors maximize innovation. They also raise significant doubts about the assumption underlying that conclusion—that different inventors will license their technologies to each other if it is efficient to do so. As Merges and Nelson suspected, uncertainty and disagreement among competitors often make licensing agreements and other coordination mechanisms unlikely and/br ineffective.  Id. at 894. Id. at 908.  Part IV. Identifying  C.  61  the Issues  Patent Administration  As discussed above, a lot of patents are being issued that are neither novel nor nonobvious, or even useful. Inevitably, much of the blame for the lack of patent quality can be traced to the sheer volume of patent applications. Intuitively, as the number of patent applications skyrockets, and the number of patent examiners stays relatively constant, the amount of review given to each patent goes down—and bad patents slip through. Let's look again at the surge in patents over the last twenty years. As illustrated in Figure 3, patent applications and issuances have nearly tripled in that time. The PTO examined over 315,000 patent applications in 2001, granting nearly 176,000 patents.  Growth has been especially fast in  software, where the number of grants has gone from hundreds to tens of thousands in just the last ten years.  25,000  350,000  300,000 A 20,000 . 250,000  - Applications - Grants  H  200,000  £ oo D  150,000  15,000  - Software Patents  10,000  100,000 A 5,000 50,000  1980  1985  1990  1995  Figure 3: U.S. Patent Activity (Total)'  2000  (j  Part IV. Identifying  62  the Issues  As shown in Table 2, for the subset of Internet and business method patents, the trend is even more dramatic.  Table 2: Internet and Business Method Patents Granted  179  Internet- Related Year  Internet  Business Methods  Business Methods  1995  163  200  2  1996  379  273  13  1997  659  390  56  1998  2217  739  178  1999  3992  999  399  2000  5745  1054  527  Unfortunately, the patent bureaucracy's budget hasn't kept pace with the exploding workload. From fiscal 1998 to 1999, patent applications rose 11%, but the PTO endured a 16% decline in how much fee revenue it was allowed to spend on operations.  180  Part of this reduction was due to the fact  that PTO revenues can be diverted to other government programs. In 1999, over $214 million was siphoned off, and in 2001, the federal budget is scheduled to divert $268 million, or nearly one quarter, from the anticipated PTO income of $1,152 billion.  181  And the PTO's hands are tied. While  a private business could just raise prices to increase its budget, the PTO may not do so without the consent of Congress.  8  182  Sources: USPTO, Internet Patent News Service (Software numbers from 1990 through 1995 are actual, while 1996 through 1999 are estimates; they include the subset Internet and Internet-related business method patents of Table 2).  9  Source: Statistical Mapping of Business Method Patents: A Research Report to the National Academy of Sciences, Board on Science, Technology, and Economic Policy (9 July 2001).  0  Philip E. Ross, "Patently Absurd Technology and gamesmanship have overwhelmed the U.S. Patent Office. How to fix it?" Forbes (29 May 2000) at 180.  1  See J.M. Hostcny, "The Sky Is Falling: Or, Over-Reaction to the Anecdote" Intell. Prop. Today (May 2000) at 8.  2  See 35 U.S.C. § 41 (1994) (providing the schedule of congressionally mandated PTO fees).  Part IV. Identifying  63  the Issues  A lack of funding means a lack of examiners. patents, or 50 apiece.  183  In 1999, 3,200 examiners awarded 161,000  In software, some 375 examiners pored over 29,000 applications and  anointed 13,900 new patents.  One software reviewer reportedly approved two hundred patents,  an average of four new awards per week, a frequency that defies doing exhaustive research of prior art to weigh a claim's uniqueness.  184  "We would have liked to hire another 750 examiners this year and  next," said Brigid Quinn, the Patent Office's spokeswoman at the time, "but budget constraints will probably preclude that."  185  Even if they had the money, the pay given to PTO examiners is hardly lucrative, ranging from $35,000 to $55,000 a year.  186  After 10 or 15 years, an examiner who has reached "Primary Examiner"  status may earn $70,000 to $80,000.  187  In contrast, the average salary for entry-level chemical  engineers was $49,150 in 1998, and for management-level engineers, between $120,000.  188  $95,000 and  Such discrepancies make it extremely difficult for the P T O to attract and retain the  skilled technical minds that it needs to examine patents properly. As admitted by the Commissioner himself, most examiners don't see the PTO as a career but rather as a stepping stone to private practice after 3 or 4 years.  189  Lack of training is also a problem—junior examiners often complain that they receive very little effective training. This is primarily because the most effective trainers—the senior examiners— do not have any incentive to spend any time training. The patent compensation system, a combination  183  Ross, supra note 180.  184  Id.  185  Id.  186  Jenna Greene, "Staking A Claim: How State Street Has Spurred A Rush On the PTO" Legal Times(\0 April 2000) at 14.  187  Robert P. Merges, "As Many as Six Impossible Patents Before Breakfast: Property Rights for Business Concepts and Patent System Reform" (1999) 14 Berkeley Tech. L.J. 577 at 607.  188  Agnes Shanley, "You and Your Job: Shifting Career Gears Can Open New Door" Chemical Engineering 1998) at 141.  189  Statement by PTO Commissioner Q. Todd Dickinson in S. Zeller, Gov. Exec. (February 2000) at 39.  (December  Part IV. Identifying  64  the Issues  of base salary and bonuses, directs their efforts heavily towards their own examining activities. There are no bonus points for training younger examiners. But as Brian Kahin, Director of the Center for Information Policy in Washington, D . C , points out, there may be more important institutional problems with the P T O . Although the agency is charged merely with the administration of the patent and trademark systems, he submits that it has been taking a much more active role, and now sees itself as a kind of crusader for stronger and more widely available patent protection. Consider the goals laid out in its Corporate Plan — 2000:  Strategic Goal:  Play a leadership role in intellectual property rights policy ...  Performance Goal:  Help protect, promote and expand intellectual property systems throughout the United States and abroad.  1  190  Not only does such a position conflict with the PTO's role as administrator of the patent system, it seriously undermines its job of advising the executive branch on intellectual property rights policy— especially since that policy strives for a utilitarian balancing of interests between public and private good. Also troublesome is the PTO's mission statement with respect to its Patent Business: "The primary mission of the Patent Business in to help customers get patents."  This contrasts  dramatically with the mission statement of the Trademark Business, which states:  "Our primary  191  mission is to apply the provisions of the Trademark Act of 1946 in the examination and registration of trademarks."  192  In the PTO Today, an internal circular, the agency even offers testimonials from its  customers: "I am pleased with the customer approach to processing patent applications as opposed to the previous, sometimes adversarial approach."  1 9 0  U.S. Patent and Trademark Office, Corporate  191  Id. at 20.  192  Id. at 38.  Plan — 2000zX. 17.  Part IV. Identifying  65  the Issues  "Examiners seemflexibleand interested in working with applicants to allow patentable subject matter to grant. Even more disconcerting is the fact that the P T O budget is directly tied to application and maintenance fees.  194  Lower standards for granting patents induce more applications, which generates  more fees. And more grants result in more maintenance fees. With this professed self-dedication to its fee-paying customers and expressed expansionist philosophy, asks Kahin, can the PTO be expected to examine patent applications energetically and even-handedly?  195  Kahin also argues that the ex parte nature of the patent application process results in marked information asymmetries which further limit the quality of issued patents.  A patent examiner deals  only with the applicant, who has the motivation and resources to convince the examiner to issue the patent.  And because of the nature of the prosecution procedure, the examiner is motivated to allow  the patent, unless there is unequivocal prior art. A large part of an examiner's pay comes from bonus points, which are accumulated only for "dispositions"—i.e., final allowances or rejections of patents. "Final" rejections, however, do not always result in the end of the examination—post-"final" action amendments and the like are often permitted—and so the only way for an examiner to earn bonus points with confidence is to allow a patent application.  196  The nature of the patent system means that patents are, in effect, rules drafted by the applicant, approved by the P T O , and then privately enforced.  The private applicant is allowed  considerably more leeway in formulating and expressing the rules (patent claims) than would a public body, so that vocabulary and terminology may vary substantially from patent to patent, especially in the case of non-technical subject matter. Even worse, the primary motivation of the patent applicant is  193  Commissioner's Page, PTO Today, Vol. 1, No. 1 Qanuary 2000).  1 9 4  35 U.S.C. § 4 2 (1994).  195  Brian Kahin, Presentation to the National Academies' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), Intellectual  196  Property Rights: How Far Should They Be Extended?(2-3  February 2000: Washington, DC).  See Brenda Sandburg, "Patent Applications Flow Freely" Legal Times(22 February 1999) at 12.  Part IV. Identifying  66  the Issues  not to make the information accessible and clear but to maximize tactical options in making use of the rules. Greg Aharonian of the Internet Patent News Service points out one of these tactical moves, what he calls one of the "games patent lawyers play."'  97  They will send in some patent claims, he says,  knowing that the examiner is going to reject them at the first office action, using up the limited art that is sent in.  They will then rewrite their claims to get around the first office action, often adding  additional claims. The examiner doesn't have any more time to find more prior art or to analyze the new claims,•• since the PTO's production system discourages continued searches—there is strong encouragement to either issue or make a final rejection. Without more time to find new artand.make a rejection, the examiner's hands are tied, and they are pretty much forced to issue the claims atthe second office^action.  198  Unfortunately, the P T O has little incentive to worry about these issues.  Although it does  makes perfunctory attempts at quality control, the basic fact is that once a patent is granted, the P T O rarely sees it again. Any bad patents it issues are then a problem for the private sector and the courts to resolve^ofteh via litigation.  D.  Pa ten t Litiga tion  By all accounts, patent litigation is on the rise. During the period 1978 to 1999, the number of patent suits rose by almost tenfold, with much of the increase occurring during the 1990s, and concentrated in the areas of pharmaceutical, biotechnology, computers, and electronics.'  197  1 9 9  Judges in the District of  Greg Aharonian, Presentation to the National Academies' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), Intellectual  198  99  Property Rights: How Far Should They Be Extended}'(2-3 February 2000: Washington, DC).  Id.  Jean O. Lanjouw & Mark Schankerman, "Enforcing Intellectual Property Rights" (2001) Presented to the National Academies' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), New Research on the Operation and Effects of the Patent System (22 October 2001: Washington, DC) at 2.  Part IV. Identifying  67  the Issues  Delaware, the district in which most U.S. companies are incorporated, recently conducted a study of trends in civil litigation and found that 13.5% of all new civil cases filed in their district are patent litigation suits.  200  The costs of litigation are not insubstantial.  The American Intellectual Property Lawyers  Association recently estimated that the average cost to litigate a patent in 1999 (for each side) was $2.1 million.  201  Nor is patent litigation quickly resolved. Estimates suggest that the average District  Court patent case lasts 31 months.  202  If you add prosecution time and appeals, it now takes  approximately 12.3 years from the-filing of a patent application to the final resolution of the lawsuits associated with it:  203  All of this has raised fears that patent litigation, or the threat of it, is impeding the ability of firms to conduct research and development effectively. A 1995 study by Josh Lerner showed that small firms avoid R&D areas where the threat of litigation from larger firms is high. ;  204  Likewise, in a  forthcoming.study, Lerner and Jean Lanjouw of Yale University and the Brookings Institute argue that the use of preliminary injunctions by large firms can discourage R&D by small firms.  205  Even if parties  can settle their patent disputes without resorting to suits, they posit, the effective threat of litigation will influence settlement terms and, ultimately, the incentives to undertake R&D.  2 0 0  Mark A. Lemley, "Reconceiving Patents in the Age of Venture Capital" (2000) 4 J. Small & Emerging Bus. L. 137 at 138.  201  James Pooley, Presentation to the National Academies' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), Intellectual  202  Property  Rights: How Far Should They Be Extended?'(2-3 February 2000: Washington, DC).  Stuart J.H. Graham, Bronwyn H. Hall, Dietmar Harhoff & David C Mowery, "Post-Issue Patent 'Quality Control': A Comparative Study of U.S. Patent Re-examinations and European Patent Oppositions" (2001) Presented to the National Academies' Board on Science, Technology and Economic Policy (STEP), New Research on the  Operation  and Effects of the Patent System (22 October 2001: Washington, DC) at 8. 2 0 3  Allison & Lemley, supra note 42. Prosecution time itself takes between 2 and 3 years. Id.  2 0 4  Josh Lerner, "Patenting in the Shadow of Competitors" (1995) 38 J. L. & Econ. 463. His study also raised serious questions about the ratio of litigation costs to R&D expenditures: "The patent litigation within USPTO and the federal courts begun in 1991 will lead to total legal expenditures (in 1991 dollars) of about $1 billion, a substantial amount relative to the $3.7 billion spent by U.S. firms on basic research in 1991." Id. at 470  205  Jean O. Lanjouw & Josh Lerner, "Preliminary Injunctive Relief: Theory and Evidence from Patent Litigation" (2002) forthcoming in J. L. & Econ.  68  Part IV. Iden tifying the Issues  In October 2001, Lerner and Lanjouw completed the most comprehensive study of patent litigation ever undertaken.  206  Using the LitAlert database provided by Derwent, a private vendor, they  found that 13,625 patent cases were filed during the period 1978-1999. Using only the "main" patent identified by each suit, and accounting for the fact that one patent could be involved in more than one suit, their data set included 9,345 patents. Using the PTO's patent classification system, these patents were separated into eight broad technology groups:  Chemical, Mechanical, Electronics (excluding  computers), Computers (including hardware and software), Biotechnology, Pharmaceutical,; Other Health, and Miscellaneous. They then matched the patent data with information from the U.S. court database organized by the Federal Judicial Center (FJC) indicating the progress or resolution of suits— i.e., whether the case is settled and at which stage of the proceedings this occurs, whether the case proceeds to trial, and the outcome of the trial.  207  Looking at the data, Lanjouw and Lerner found that, because of the sharp increase in patent activity, filing rates for patent suits have been roughly constant over the last two decades—i.e., the growth in litigation has been comparable to the growth in patenting itself. The authors found that the total number of patent applications grew by 71% over the period, with patenting nearly tripling in Drugs, Biotechnology, and Medical Instruments, and quadrupling in Computers.  208  Table 3, on the  next page, shows the filing rates (in cases per thousand) for the various groups, broken down into three sub-periods: 1978-84, 1985-90, and 1991-95.  Notice that the filing rates are much lower for  Chemical, Mechanical, and Electronics, and much higher for Computers, Biotechnology, and Other Health.  Lanjouw & Lerner, supra note 199. The authors set included all cases coded 830 by the FJC. However, since some patent-related cases may have been coded under other categories by the court {e.g., because the patent issue was part of a broader contractual dispute), the authors admit that a small percentage of cases identified in Derwent are not in the FJC database. In addition, the database runs only through the end of 1997. Id.  Part IV. Identifying  69  the Issues  Table 3: Patent Filing Rates, by Technology Field and Time Period ' 2  Technology Field  1978-84  1985-90  1991-95  Total: 1978-95  Chemical  11.6  10.9  13.0  11.8  Mechanical  17.7  14.5  18.7  16.9  Electronics  16.2  13.1  16.8  15.4  Computers  32.6  21.2  25.9  25.6  Biotechnology  33.3  27.6  25.5  27.9  Pharmaceutical  22.S  18.9  24.3  22.2  Other Health  48.2  35.2  27.3  34.6  Miscellaneous  32.4  28.9  40.7  34.2  Total  19.3  16.6  21.1  19.0  Lanjouw and Lerner then looked at the number of claims and the number of citations per claim for the patents in their data set, and compared them to a control set of randomly selected patents.  210  They found that the litigated patents had far more claims than the control set, and also more forward citations per claim (i.e., more patents cite them than cite the control group) and fewer backward cites per claim (i.e., they cite less patents on average than the control group, an indication that the technology area is not well-developed and innovation is less likely to be derivative).  Both of these  findings indicate that valuable patents are more likely to be involved in litigation. The authors then perform a detailed analysis of three primary litigation metrics—the probability of filing a suit, the probability of settlement after a suit is filed (including the timing of such settlements), and the plaintiff win probability for cases at trial—as related to the type of the firm involved. They found that publicly-listed (i.e., large) companies are far less likely to file suits on their patents—their mean filing rate was 10.4 suits per thousand patents, as compared to about 45 suits for  209  Source: Id. The authors note that these filing rates may be understated, however, since they were calculated using only the main patents in each suit, when in fact there may be several patents per suit, especially in areas like biotechnology.  2 1 0  For each litigated patent, a "matched" patent having the same application year and primary patent classification code was chosen from at random from the set of all U.S. patents (both litigated and unlitigated).  Part IV. Identifying  70  the Issues  unlisted companies and individuals. " Moreover, filing rates for foreign patentees (mostly unlisted 2  firms) were much lower than for their domestic counterparts. Lanjouw and Lerner explain this difference in filing rates by looking to the firm's size, and hypothesizing that size presents two advantages. First, firms with large patent portfolios may be better able to settle disputes through trading (i.e., cross-licensing) intellectual property, without resorting to suits. Second, assuming that smaller firms are less able to finance expensive patent litigation, relatively large firms may be better able to settle because they pose greater litigation threats when confronting smaller firms. And when large firms have disputes with each other, they are likely to have many points of interaction other than trading intellectual property, especially through competition in product markets, and this interaction in other dimensions should promote settlement. , Theciata confirmed these hypotheses. For a small (unlisted) company with a small portfolio of 100 patents (cumulative over a 10-year period), the. average probability of litigating a given patent is 7.8 percent. , For a similar company but with a moderate portfolio of 500 patents, the figure drops to. only 2.0%.  212  The authors found that the marginal effect of patent portfolio size is stronger for smaller  companies (as measured by employment), which indicates that for smaller firms, having a portfolio of patents to trade is likely to_be the key mechanism for avoiding litigation. Lanjouw and Lerner's most important finding, however, was that the post-suit outcomes—the probability of settlement and the plaintiff win rates at trial—are almost completely independent of firm or portfolio size. From a policy perspective, this is good news because it means that enforcement of patent rights depends on the effective threat of court action more than on extensive, post-suit legal proceedings which consume court resources.  This conclusion was reinforced by the two additional  findings: first, that about 80 percent of all patent suits filed are settled by the parties before trial; and  211  Id. The authors assume that the listed companies are generally bigger than the unlisted ones. They also measure size more directly by looking to how many people the companies employ.  2 1 2  Id.  Part IV. Identifying  71  the Issues  second, that most settlement occurs soon after the suit is filed, often before the pre-trial hearing is held.  213  The bad news, of course, is that individuals and small firms, as we saw, are much more likely  to be involved in suits—and no more likely to resolve those disputes quickly in post-suit settlements. In the end, it seems that-patent litigation only tells a small part of the story of how the patent system works as a whole. As we saw in Table 3, only 19 out of every 1,000 patents are ever involved in litigation, or about 2 percent.  O f those 19, only about 4 ever go to court—80% are settled  beforehand. That means that out of the 175,983 patents granted last year, only about 670 will ever see court time. Mark Lemley, Professor of Law at the University of California, Berkeley, calls the other 99.6% of patents the "missing patents/'  214  The overwhelming number of patentees are spending the  money to get patents—a sum he estimates to be almost $5 billion a year—and then not enforcing them. Of course, a number of phenomena we've already looked at go a long way to explaining most of the, so-called.missing patents.  As observed by Lanjouw and Lerner, one of the primary "new uses"  for patents is-cross-licensing between firms. Although such patents are not enforced in the traditional sense, they do end up being extremely valuable for firms which might otherwise be forced to litigate instead. Another related use for the missing patents is simply defensive.  The threat of litigation can  quickly be negated if a firm has a patent portfolio with which to threaten back. A third main use, one which is more valuable to smaller firms lacking significant patent portfolios, is that of financing tool. Although venture capitalists may not like the risks associated with the actual use of patents in litigation, they love patents as a concrete indicator of the value of a start-up company. Another recent study by Kortum and Lerner found that there is a strong positive relationship between venture capital financing  213  2 1 4  2 1 5  Id. See Lemley, supra note 200. He estimates that at a prosecution cost of $25,000 per patent, $5 billion per year is paid to patent lawyers and the PTO. Id. at 1 38. He refines these numbers in his next essay—see infra note 387 and accompanying text.  Part IV. Identifying  12  the Issues  and patenting— that is, the amount of venture capital activity in an industry significantly increases its r  rate of patenting.  216  In addition, inventors may choose to prosecute patents for other reasons.  Some companies  patent just so they have a registry of their ideas. After inventing something, they patent it, in the same way that scientists might, in other fields, publish it.  The company then has an official government  record saying'that they invented this thing on this date.  Similarly, particularly in academic settings,  patents may be used as internal yardsticks for progress in research and development, with companies or research labs measuring how innovative they are by how many patents they have.  In this sense,  a patent may be an end to itself for a scientist who will be rewarded for getting it or just wants to put it on his resume. • We've seen the emergence of licensing shops, like Walker Digital, whose sole business purpose is not to create innovative products, but merely to accumulate and license patents.  Other  individuals may just be "paper patenting"—inventing something, but rather that building it themselves, licensing out. the technology, or even worse, suing others who try to build it.  Or there may be  companies at the end of their useful technological life, so to speak, whose major asset is not new technology, but patents they acquired ten or fifteen years ago when they were a more productive entity. It also seems that patents are to be used simply as indicators of product differentiation or branding, or to enhance the image of the patenting entity with an aura of creativity and technological proficiency.  217  Consider the 1999 release of the Oral-B CrossAction toothbrush.  In a television  commercial announcing its entry into the market, a baritone-voiced narrator touted its uniqueness and high-tech nature and advised viewers that there had been three years of development, three hundred  2 1 6  Samuel Kortum & Josh Lerner, "Does Venture Capital Spur Innovation?" (1998) National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W6846.  Part IV. Identifying  73  the Issues  scientific studies, and over twenty-three patents filed in relation to its innovative tooth brushing properties.  218  The discovery that 339 patents have been issued in the past 25 years relating to hair-  brushes—heated, flocked, vented, bendable, extendable, foldable, and self-cleaning hair-brushes, brushes for straightening, curling, colouring and cutting hair, at least one combination brush and shoehorn, and a birth-control pill dispenser in the form of a hair-brush—begs the question as to how much money was spent securing those patents, what returns were generated, and how they could possibly enable monopoly hair-brush profits that were not attainable through effective marketing and efficient distribution.  219  • All in all, much of the focus of academic inquiry, especially among legal scholars, needs to be aimed away from the small number of cases that turn up in court toward the large number of patents revealed in these broader uses. Attention should be paid to the new players, as well—the venture capitalists, the company researchers, the university scientists, and those who patent just because they can.  E.  The Disconnect  Starting in 1980, there began a series of radical changes to patent policy and practice in the United States that have had the generally-perceived effect of strengthening the protection that patents provide and extending the applicability of that protection both institutionally and technologically.  Roughly  coincident in time with these changes, there was an unprecedented surge in both patenting and R&D spending. Despite the significance of the policy changes and wide availability of detailed patent data, however, robust conclusions as to their effect on technological innovation are disappointingly few.  2 1 7  See Ann Bartow, "Separating Marketing Innovation from Actual Invention: A Proposal for a New, Improved, Lighter, and Better-Tasting Form of Patent Protection" (2000) 4 J. Small & Emerging Bus. L. 1.  2 , 8  2l9  Id. at 3.  /</at4.  ^  Part IV. Identifying  74  the Issues  Indeed, it appears that the increases in patenting and R&D spending are mostly unrelated to the changes in the patent system. For some, this isn't much of a surprise. Economists have known for some time that patents are not the most important mechanism for preserving incentives for innovation. Likewise, they've always been unsure as to what impact patents actually have on innovation. In a 1958 study commissioned by the U.S. Congress, economist Fritz Machlup came to the remarkable a conclusion that if we didn't have: a patent system, it would be irresponsible to create one, but since we have one, it would be irresponsible to eliminate it—hardly a ringing endorsement of the patent model of innovation.  220  Prominent Yale economist George Priest, meanwhile, has'been quoted as saying that economic analysis' of the patent system, is "one of the least productive lines of inquiry in all of economic thought."  221  It seems that there now exists a major disconnect between patenting and innovation. The lack of economic evidence that strengthening the patent system led to increased innovation highlights this disconnect.  As do the uses for the "missing patents" discussed above.  Another reason is that the  economy that existed in 1790, and the original patent model devised at the time—the individual innovator toiling away in his basement on some new-fangled mechanical marvel—are enormously at odds with the current reality.  Today, the inventor named on a patent is more often than not a  company, not an individual. In 1885, only 12 percent of patents were issued to corporations; now, only 12 percent of patents are issued to independent inventors.  222  The individual scientist at a company  or a university doesn't go about his research with the immediate goal of obtaining patents for his work, since he is almost never directly rewarded by the patent—the company is. Most employee agreements' explicitly relinquish all rights to any inventions developed during the course of a researcher's employment. Patenting may be the furthest thing from his mind.  Mark Lemley, "Reconceiving Patents in the Age of Venture Capital" (2000) 4 J. Small & Emerging Bus. L. 137 at 139. 2 2 1  222  Id.  Merges, supra note 37, at 2215.  Part IV. Identifying  the Issues  75  Through two centuries of economic upheaval, the basic tenets of the patent system remain virtually unchanged, especially the insistence to remain subject-matter neutral. The U.S. patent system now reigns over vast new industries never conceived of by its original founders: computers, computer software, biotechnology, and even the methods of doing business themselves. Is it realistic to expect a system devised over 200 years ago to function smoothly today? With somewhat of a tenuous link to begin.with, it's no surprise that the patent system has lost touch with its old friend innovation. So the question is, what do we do? How do we reestablish the link between innovation and the patent system? Or at least minimize the problems? In the next section, I'll examine the fixes that have been implemented so far, and look at a number of solutions which have so far remained proposals.  76  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  V.  F O R M U L A T I N G T H E  S O L U T I O N S  A number of solutions to the problems with the U.S. patent system have been proposed over the last two to three years. Some, like those contained in the American Inventors Protection Act of 1999, have been implemented.  Others, like shorter terms or special standards for business methods, have not.  Other proposals aimed at fine-tuning patent administration or reinforcing the various scope-limiting doctrines look promising, and may soon find support among the various policy players.  A. The  Reform To Date problems presented by business method patenting have not gone unnoticed by American  lawmakers. On 29 November 1999, President Clinton signed into law a bill containing the American Inventors Protection Act of 1999 (AIPA).  223  The AIPA is actually a collection of seven different acts  aimed at: (1) establishing a "first inventor" defense against business method patent infringement actions; (2) allowing pre-grant publication of patent applications; (3) establishing an interpartes patent reexamination procedure; (4) extending patent terms to remedy delays in the patent registration process; (5) creating a legal claim against fraudulent invention promoters; (6) reorganizing the Patent and Trademark Office; and (7) lowering various patent and trademark registration fees.  1.  FIRST I N V E N T O R D E F E N S E  One of the main concerns in the wake of the State Street decision was the possibility that latecomers to the e-commerce field would suddenly start to assert newly-obtained business method patents against  223  American Inventors Protection Act of 1999, Pub. L. No. 106-113, 113 Stat. 1501, codified as amended in scattered sections of Title 35. The AIPA was passed as part of the Intellectual Property and Communications Omnibus Reform Act.  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  11  those who had previously been conducting their businesses using the now-patented methods. The AIPA made an attempt to address such concerns with the First Inventor Defense Act of 1999,  224  under which a party can establish a defense to a patent infringement suit by proving, by clear and convincing evidence, that the party, acting in good faith, actually reduced the subject matter of the asserted patent, claim(s) to practice at least one year before the effective filing date of the application that led to the issuance of the patent-in-suit, and that the party commercially used, either in public or in secret, the subject matter of the claim(s) before the effective filing date of the application^!.e., was the first to invent the disputed invention (though not the first to patent it).  225  The first inventor defense applies only to patents for "methods of doing or conducting business"  226  and thus appears to be intended to address the types of business method inventions that had  generally been considered unpatentable prior to State Street.  121  It should be noted, however, that the  AlPA provides ho definition for the phrase "methods of doing or conducting business," and thus it is conceivable that courts may ultimately construe the defense to be more broadly applicable to other types of methods used in the course of business. The prior user defense is personal to the party who actually made the prior use, but may be asserted by one who purchases a "useful end product" produced by the patented method.  228  The  defense is not transferable except as part of the transfer of the entire business of the original owner of the defense. While the original owner may expand the use of the patented method both as to quantity  2 2 4  First Inventor Defense Act of 1999, Pub. L. No. 106-113, § 4302, 113 Stat. 1501 at 1501A-555 to -557, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 273.  225  "Commercial use" is defined as "use of a method in the United States, so long as such use is in connection with an internal commercial use or an actual arm's length sale or other arm's length commercial transfer of a useful end result, whether or not the subject matter at issue is accessible to or otherwise known to the public." Id. § 4302, 113 Stat. 1501 at 1501A^5S5, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 273(a)(1).  2 2 6  2 2 7  See id. § 4302, 113 Stat, at 1501A-556, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 273(b)(3)(A). Indeed, State Streetwas specifically mentioned as the rationale for the defense's inclusion. See Brenda Sandburg, "Patent Reform Redux" Intel! Prop. Mag. (July 1999).  2 2 8  See Guy R. Gosnell, Michael S. Connor, and Donald M. Hill Jr., "The American Inventors Protection Act Makes Significant Changes to Patent Laws and Addresses Harmonization" New York Law Journal (24 April 2000) at S5.  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  78  of usage and the number of "sites" at which it is used without losing the defense, a transferee may use the method only at "sites" at which it had been used prior to the later of the transfer or the effective filing date of the patent. How the term "site" is to be construed in the world of e-commerce will be an interesting question for the courts to resolve. The First Inventor Defense Act was quickly criticized as an ineffective fix to the problem of business method patents. In order to prevent the first inventor from competing away all patent profits, the defense can be asserted only by the party who can establish the defense and it can only be used with respect to the specific subject matter claimed.  229  Furthermore, it can create effective competition only  when there is someone who was positioned, before the application was filed, to enter the patentee's business.  230  Even more troublesome for those who want the business method exception reinstated is  that fact that by creating the defense, Congress may be viewed as having implicitly endorsed the patenting of methods of doing business.  2.  231  -  N E W PUBLICATION RULES  Contrary to practice in most foreign countries, including Europe and Japan, patent applications in the United States were not published until after a patent was issued. This practice was intended to protect the inventor while the PTO reviews the application, a process which generally takes eighteen to twenty months or longer. With the Domestic Publication of Foreign Filed Patent Applications Act of 1999,  See 35 U.S.C.A. § 273(b)(6) & (b)(3)(C) (West Supp. 2000). See Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss, "Are Business Method Patents Bad for Business?" (2000) 16 Computer & High Tech. L.J. 263 at 272. For additional criticisms, see Frederic M. Meeker & Gary D. Fedorochkof, "How strong is first inventor defense?" The National Law Journal(24 July 2000) at Cl 3. Domestic Publication of Foreign Filed Patent Applications Act of 1999, Pub. L. No. 106-113, §§ 4502-4506, 113 Stat. 1501A-561, codified at scattered sections of Title 35.  232  Part V. Formulating  79  the Solutions  the AIPA moved U.S. law closer toward that of other major countries by mandating the worldwide publication of.pending patent applications eighteen months after they are filed.  233  In addition to harmonization, one of the main purposes of the Act was to prevent the scurrilous practice of "submarine patents," whereby an unscrupulous "inventor" files a large, vaguely-worded patent, then delays its issuance by filing numerous continuations and amendments, hoping that an industry will develop while the application is secret so that he may later "surface" the patent and extract royalties from;those who innocently adopted the technology.  234  The change wrought by the Domestic Publication of Foreign Filed Patent Applications Act is not as drastic as it first appears, however, because publication can be avoided if the applicant certifies when filing the application that the invention disclosed in the application has not and will not be the subject of any application filed in any foreign country that requires publication of applications 18 months after filing.  235  Thus, only applications that would have been published abroad anyway will  be subject to publication.  See id. § 4502, 113 Stat, at 1501A-561, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 122(b)(1)(A). The new publication provisions apply to any application filed on or after 29 November 2000. While the Act gives discretion to the Patent Office Director to determine what, if any, information concerning published patent applications will be made available to the public, the Patent Office has given some indications that the entire application file will generally be laid open when an application is published. See Gosnell, et al., supra note 228. Sec Steve Blount, "The Use of Delaying Tactics to Obtain Submarine Patents and Amend Around a Patent that a Competitor Has Designed Around" (1999) 81 J. Pat. & Trademark Off. Soc'y 11. Although vehemently denied, those in favor of the pre-issue publication legislation alleged that many of the "small independent inventors' groups" opposing patent reform are actually submariners funded by the Jerome Lemelson Foundation, set up in 1997 after the death of the titular inventor who made hundreds of millions suing companies for patent infringement of his bar code patents. See Cyndia Zwahlen, "Big Firms, Independents at Odds on Patent Plan" L.A. Times (13 October 1999)atC12. Domestic Publication of Foreign Filed Patent Applications Act of 1999, supra note 232, § 4502, 113 Stat, at 1501A561, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 154(b)(2)(B)(i).  Part V. Formulating  3.  80  the Solutions  INTER PARTES R E E X A M I N A T I O N  Under the law prior to the AIPA, a third party only had two basic options for contesting the validity of an issued patent—raise a claim of invalidity as a defense to an infringement allegation in court, or file a request in the Patent Office for an reexamination of the patent. than litigation,  Reexamination is far less expensive  but because the entire reexamination proceeding was closed to participation by the  third party, it was rarely used.  237  The Optional Inter Partes Reexamination Procedure Act of 1999 established a new P T O reexamination proceeding with the participation of both the patent applicant and third-party initiators.  238  This new in ter partes procedure supplements the existing ex parte reexamination system  and applies to any patent issuing from an application filed on or after 29 November 1999.  Similar to  ex parte reexamination, an inter partes reexamination is initiated by a third party filing a request in the Patent Office, typically citing some prior art that had not been previously considered by the Patent Office in the original prosecution of the patent.  239  If the Patent Office determines that there is a  "substantial new question of patentability" raised by the request, an inter partes reexamination is initiated.  240  The standards for conducting the new inter partes proceedings are similar to those used for the  ex parte proceedings,  241  but unlike ex parte reexamination, the third-party requester can participate  It costs $2,520 to file for reexamination (37 C.F.R. § 1.20(c)), and practitioners estimate the average costs of the procedure at $10,000 to $100,000, depending on the complexity of the matter. Litigation, on the other hand, costs between $1 million and $3 million. See Graham, etal., supra note 202, at 8. See "IP Subcommittee Chairman Coble Explains Recent Changes To Patent Reform Bill" (19 August 1999) 58 Pat., Trademark & Copyright J. 486. It was therefore called an ex parte procedure—the third party could only start the process and provide some initial information; the rest of the procedure involved only the patentee. Optional Inter Partes Reexamination Procedure Act of 1999, Pub. L. No. 106-113, §§ 4602-07, 113 Stat. 1501A567, 1501A-567to-S71, codified at scattered sections of Title 35. See American Inventors Protection Act of 1999, Pub. L. No. 106-113, § 4604, 113 Stat. 1501, 1S01A-567, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 311(a). Id. § 4 6 0 4 , 113 Stat, at 1S01A-568, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 312(a). See id. § 4604, 113 Stat, at 1S01A-568, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 314(a).  Part V. Formulating  81  the Solutions  beyond the initial filing by challenging any Office Action taken by the P T O , or any patentee response to an Office Action.  242  Only written submissions will be allowed, however; the Patent Office has  indicated an intention not to permit either party to conduct interviews with the examiner during the reexamination. The adoption of the inter partes proceeding was widely heralded as a reinvigoration of the reexamination procedure.  As enacted, however, the law was saddled with so much extra baggage  detrimental to the third party's rights that it is doubtful that the new proceedings will be used much either. First, the new law severely restricts the third party's rights to appeal an adverse determination. The third party can appeal a decision of the Patent Office upholding the patentability of a patent claim only to the Board of Patent Appeals and Interferences, and then to the Federal Circuit; there is no right to appeal to U.S. district court.  243  Likewise, if the Patent Office decides adversely to the patent owner,  it must first appeal to the Board, and can appeal the Board's decision only to the Federal Circuit. This limitation on the patent owner's appeal rights also now applies to ex parte reexamination.  244  Second, drastic estoppel effects arise for the requester in an inter partes reexamination. The third party is estopped, in any later civil action, from asserting the invalidity of any claim on any ground that it raised or could have raised in the reexamination.  245  The third party is also estopped from  challenging any fact determined during the reexamination, unless the determination is later proved to be erroneous based on information that was unavailable at the time of the reexamination.  246  Few  See id. § 4604, 113 Stat, at 1S01A-568 to -S69, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 314(b)(3). See id. § 4604, 113 Stat, at 1501A-569, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 315(a)-(b). See Gosnell, et al., supranote  228.  See id. § 4604, 113 Stat, at 1501A-569, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 315(c). See id. § 4607, 113 Stat, at 1501A-571. It is unclear what will be considered "unavailable," given that all prior art, by definition, is publicly available.  Part V. Formulating  the  82  Solutions  patent lawyers will be willing to risk a reexamination request for a client knowing that the client will be precluded from arguing the same factual issues in litigation. Another limitation of reexamination is that it may only be used to call attention to prior patents or printed publications and not to bring forward less conspicuous categories of prior art—such as prior knowledge or use by others—that are more likely to have escaped the attention of the examiner.  247  In addition, reexamination is generally conducted by the patent examiner who conducted  the original examination, who may be difficult to persuade that his own prior decision to award the patent was wrong. There is also the concern that third-party participation could be used as an effective delaying tactic; for well-heeled companies trying to subvert smaller competitors' patents.  "That's a killer,"  warns Robert W . Fletcher, president of Intellectual Property Insurance Services, a private firm that manages IP policies for major insurers.  "The concept of a third party being able to initiate re-  examination and continue to participate in the process, even to the point of appealing an unsuccessful endeavor to defeat a patent, goes far beyond the means of a small inventor and, thus, essentially puts him in peril," he says. "He'll be forced to first litigate the merits of his invention before he has the opportunity to sue for damages, where he'll again be called upon to litigate validity and infringement »248  issues.  4.  OTHER AIPA  CHANGES  Prior to the implementing legislation that came about as a result of the 1994 Uruguay Round Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS), United States patents  2 4 7  See 35 U.S.C. § 301 (governing citations of prior art); 35 U.S.C. § 302 (regulating requests for reexaminations).  2 4 8  Steven Andersen, "Presumed Invalid? Pending Bill Would Alter Patent System" Corporate  Legal Times (November  1999) at 1. "That's wonderful for my business," he concludes. "I'm going to start selling re-examination insurance.  Part V. Formulating  the  83  Solutions  had a term of seventeen years from the date of issue. In order to harmonize U.S. patent terms with the rest of the world, the 17-year term was changed to a 20-year term, but running from the filing date of the application, not the date of issue.  249  -Since that time, however, there has been concern that because of delays in the prosecution process, some patents may be receiving effective terms substantially shorter than the seventeen years once granted. The AIPA's Patent Term Guarantee Act of 1999 attempts to guarantee'that Patent Office delay will not result in less than a 17-year term by extending a, patent's term to the extent that processing delays effectively shortened the term.  250  In other words, the patent term of an invention is  extended by one day for each day the PTO failed to meet statutory deadlines, and for each day the patent application was delayed due to interferences, secrecy orders, or appeals.  251  The new law also  guarantees no more than a three-year application process, with each day over the three-year deadline being added to the granted patent term.  252  The applicant, however, must "engage in reasonable efforts  to conclude the prosecution of the application" or else the patent term extension may be shortened.  253  The AIPA also makes an attempt to deter fraudulent "invention promoters"—those organizations and agents advertised in the back of trade publications and on late-night television—from taking advantage of unsuspecting inventors. It has been estimated that such promoters annually milk more than $ 100 million from first-time inventors seeking assistance in the marketing and protection of their inventions.  The Inventors' Rights Act imposes upon invention promoters a duty to disclose:  (1) how many inventions they evaluated in the past five years; (2) how many customers contracted with them in the past five years; (3) how many customers "received net financial profits" or license  Every inventor better have some, because once he gets involved in the application process, God knows how much it will cost him to get through re-examination." 2 4 9  See 35 U.S.C. § 154(a)(2) (1994).  2 5 0  Patent Term Guarantee Act ofl 999, Pub. L. No. 106-113, § 4402, 113 Stat. 1S01A-557 at 1501A-557 to -SS9, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 154(b)(1).  251  See /</. § 4402, 113 Stat, at 1501 A-557 to-559, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 154(b)(1)(A), (C).  2 5 2  See /</. § 4402, 113 Stat, at 1501A-558, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 154(b)(1)(B).  Part V. Formulating  84  the Solutions  agreements as a result of the invention promoter's services; and (4) "the names and addresses of all previous invention promotion companies with which the promoter [was] affiliated in the past ten years."  If the invention promoter makes a fraudulent representation, a material omission of fact, or  254  violates his or her duty to disclose, an injured customer can bring a civil action to recover actual damages, reasonable costs, and attorneys' fees. the Act provides for treble damages.  255  In cases of intentional misconduct by the promoter,  256  The two-other AIPA acts are aimed at the operation of the Patent Office.  The Patent and  Trademark Office Efficiency Act reorganizes the PTO and establishes it as a Department of Commerce agency.  The new P T O ultimately retains most of its independence, although the Secretary of  257  Commerce determines the PTO's policy directions.  258  The presidentially-appointed head of the P T O  is considered both the Under-Secretary of Commerce for Intellectual Property and the Director of the PTO.  2 5 9  In addition, the new law creates a Patent Public Advisory Committee and a Trademark Public  Advisory Committee to advise the PTO withrespect to its "policies, goals, performance, budget, and user fees.  260  Each committee is comprised of nine members, each of whom are appointed by the  253  Id. § 4402, 113 Stat, at 1S01A-5S9, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 154(b)(2)(C)(i).  2 5 4  Inventors' Rights Act, Pub. L. No. 106-113, § 4102, 113 Stat. 1501A-SS2 at 1S01A-552 to -554, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 297., An "invention promoter" is "any person, firm, partnership, corporation, or other entity who offers to perform or performs invention promotion services for, or on behalf of, a customer." Id. § 4102, 113 Stat, at 1501A-553, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 297(c)(3). An invention promotion service is "the procurement or attempted procurement for a customer of a firm, corporation, or other entity to develop and market products or services that include the invention of a customer." Id. § 4102, 113 Stat, at 1501A-554, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 297(c)(4).  255  See id. § 4102, 113 Stat, at 1S01A-SS3, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 297(b)(1)(A). Alternatively, the injured customer can elect to recover statutory damages of up to $5,000 any time before final judgment in lieu of actual damages— see id. § 4 1 0 2 , 113 Stat, at 1S01A-SS3, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 297(b)(1)(B).  2 5 6  See id. § 4102, 113 Stat, at 1501A-5S3, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 297(b)(2).  2 5 7  Patent and Trademark Office Efficiency Act, Pub. L. No. 106-113, §§ 4711-4719, 113 Stat. 1501A-S72 at 1S01A572 to -581, codified in scattered sections of Title 35.  2 5 8  2 5 9  See H. Rep. No. 106-287 at 60-61 (1999). See American Inventors Protection Act of 1999, Pub. L. No. 106-113, § 4713, 113 Stat. 1501 at 1S01A-S7S, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 3(a)(1).  260  Id. § 4714, 113 Stat, at 1501A-578 to -579, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 5(a)(1), (d)(1).  Part V. Formulating  the  85  Solutions  Secretary of Commerce to "represent interests of diverse users . . . representing small and large entity applicants."  261  -  • .  Finally, the Patent and Trademark Fee Fairness Act of 1999 reduces P T O patent fees by approximately ten percent.  262  It also provides for a study of alternative fee structures aimed at  maximizing inventor participation.  5.  263  THE P T O "ACTION PLAN"  Not all reform has been congressionally driven. On 29 March 2000, the Patent and Trademark Office announced, an "Action Plan" to address the onslaught of business method patents.  264  The Plan consists  of two parts: "Industry Outreach" and "Quality." Under the Industry Outreach component, the Patent Office plans to establish a so-called Customer Partnership with the software, Internet and e-commerce industry.  Customer "partners" will meet with P T O representatives on a quarterly basis to identify  problems and discuss solutions for the examination of business method patents. The PTO also intends to convene a Roundtable Forum on business method patents and to initiate a program to obtain industry feedback on prior art resources.  The Quality portion of the plan includes a pledge by the Patent Office to enhance technical training of examiners, to revise the Examination Guidelines for Computer-related Inventions and to expand current prior art search activities conducted by examiners during the review of such applications.  261  262  265  In the event that the examination of a business method patent application results in an  See id. § 4714, 133 Stat, at 1501A-S79, codified at 35 U.S.C. § 5(b)(l)-(2). Patent and Trademark Fee Fairness Act of 1999, Pub. L. No. 106-113, § 4202, 113 Stat. 1501A-554 at 1501A-554, amending 35 U.S.C. § 41(a)(1)(A), (a)(4)(A), (a)(10), (b)(1).  263  2 6 4  See. id. § 4 1 0 4 , 113 Stat, at 1S01A-S5S. United States Patent and Trademark Office, Business Methods Patent Initiatives: An Action Plan, available at http: / /www. uspto.gov /web/offices/com/sol/actionplan.html.  Part V. Formulating  86  the Solutions  initial decision of allowable subject matter, the Patent Office will initiate a new second-level review of the allowed application to insure compliance with search requirements and to evaluate the scope of the allowed patent claims. The Plan also vows to substantially increase the number of business method patents selected for an independent quality review prior to issuance.  B.  266  Business Method Reform  Other reform has been suggested but not implemented, most of it aimed either at business method patenting or the Patent Office itself. Proposed business method reform has included a revisiting of the business method- exception, shorter terms for business method and software patents, and the < introduction of a new bill aimed at improving the quality of business method patents.  1.  '  REVISITING T H E BUSINESS M E T H O D E X C E P T I O N  Considering the difficulties that business method patents have presented to the U.S. patent system, a number of prominent commentators, including Rochelle Cooper Dreyfuss, Professor of Law at the New York University School of Law and Director of the Engelberg Center on Innovation Law and Policy, have called for the business method exception to be reinstated. "Given the problem of business method patents, a strong argument can be made that State Street should be reversed, either judicially or legislatively."  267  Notwithstanding issues of patent quality and overbreadth, she even questions the value of valid business method patents: "I believe that they adversely affect innovation, and worse, the economy." Why? First, she claims, they lack justification.  268  Without any specific thought given to the need for  2 6 6  See Peter R. Lando, "Business Method Patents: Update Post State Street" (2001) 9 Tex. Intell. Prop. L.J. 403.  2 6 7  Dreyfuss, supra note 230, at 277.  Part V. Formulating  87  the Solutions  protection, business methods have come under the aegis of intellectual property simply because they have value, she says.  Neither the free-rider problem nor the disclosure rationale justifies business  method patents—businesses are largely practiced in public, and due to their dependence on compensation schemes, lines of reporting, supervising policies and other business factors, business methods are hard to take a free ride on. While business innovations are certainly desirable, it is not at all clear that patents are needed in order to spur people to create them.  Traditional business  mechanisms such lock-in, network effects, lead time, and good old-fashioned loyalty already go a long way to assuring returns adequate to recoup costs and earn substantial profit. "Furthermore, the patenting of business methods inflicts unacceptable costs, primarily because what is being patented is too close to the conceptual level, too far from specific application. Just as sports moves should not be patentable, contends Professor Dreyfuss, neither should business methods. Like in sports, "winning and losing in business is supposed to depend on execution, not on exclusive rights to the moves that need to be executed.  We want the best book store to dominate the market,  not the store that makes it easiest to check out."  269  It is unlikely, however, that the Federal Circuit will repudiate or seriously limit the State  Street decision. In April 1999, in AT&T v. Excel Communications, a different Federal Circuit panel went out of its way to approve the reasoning of State Street and repudiate earlier opinions inconsistent with it.  270  And later that year, in WMS Gaming Inc. v. Internationa] Game Technology, the court  again rejected the business method exception.  271  It is even more unlikely that the Supreme Court will  Id. at 274.  Id. at 276. She continues, "Or, just as sporting events identify the best athlete and team, market competition is what this society relies on to determine the best uses for particular resources. If that mechanism is distorted, then Adam Smith's unseen hand is crippled." AT&T  Corp.  v. Excel Communications,  184 F.3d 1339 (Fed. Cir. 1999).  supra note 20.  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  88  enter the fray. It denied certiorari m. State Street and AT&T v. Excel, and showed no real interest in addressing the matter when it did so.  272  A legislated prohibition is slightly more conceivable, business method patenting, also very remote.  273  but due to the inertia now behind  As Pamela Samuelson says, such a ban is "politically  unlikely since the most organized [lobby] group on this issue is the patent lawyers."  274  And since  business method patents mean more business for the patent bar, they would never go along with such a drastic reform. Indeed, in 1999, the Intellectual Property Law Section of the American Bar Association passed a resolution supporting the patentability of "computer-implemented inventions encompassing business methods,  user  interfaces,  algorithms,  performance  enhancements,  data  structures,  usability  enhancements or other inventions which have a beneficial result or other practical application."  275  In a  recent ABA Journal article, past IPL section chair Gregory J. Maier asserted that critics highlight "a few inane patents" to portray the entire system "as a dysfunctional national disaster."  276  The argument that  patents have escaped the tangible, nuts-and-bolts world is simply nonsense, he said. Section chair-elect Charles P. Baker of New York City toed the same line, citing the section's formal opposition, expressed in another resolution passed in late 2000, to "any amendment or interpretation [of section 101] that excludes business methods from the class of statutory subject matter."  277  2 7 2  1 19 S.Ct. 851 (1999); 120S.Ct. 368 (1999).  2 7 3  It was done with medical and surgical procedures—in 1996, out of concern that such patents limited patients' access to medical procedures, affected doctors' ability to practice their profession responsibly, and imposed undue costs on consumers, Congress amended 35 U.S.C. 287 to eliminate the remedies available to owners of medical procedure patents. See 35 U.S.C. 287(c) (Supp. 1998); Pub. L. No. 104-208, 616, 104 Stat. 3009-67 (1996). The law did not eliminate the ability to obtain such patents, but the inability to enforce them essentially produced the same result. See Thomas, supra note 97, at 47-50.  2 7 4  Smith, supra note 108.  275  Id.  276  Id.  277  Id.  I  89  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  2.  SHORTER TERMS  As mentioned above, on 9 March 2000, Amazon founder and C E O Jeff Bezos leaped into the business method debate by posting a three-page reform proposal on his Web site suggesting that the patent terms for software and business method patents be limited to three to five years.  278  Such a duration, he  said, would be enough to grant a head start in the market, but without stifling competition for years to come. The Patent Office issued a terse one-paragraph response to the Bezos letter: "We believe the existing patent law works very well for all technologies."  279  Other critics were more verbose. Herbert  Schwartz, a patent litigation partner at New York's Fish & Neave, warned of a slippery slope.: Changes of the magnitude Mr. Bezos proposes "could be the unraveling of the patent system," he warned. Special consideration sought by Internet and software companies today could lead to similar accommodations made to other industries. "I am troubled by the broader notion that Mr. Bezos and his industry are entitled to special protection," he said.  280  Furthermore, as a practical matter, a switch  to shorter terms would require a costly restructuring of innumerable complex licensing and other contractual relations based on the traditional twenty-year term for software patents.  Regardless of these concerns, however, one problem seems to trump the idea of shorter terms, at least for software patents.  As pointed out by Michael Kirk, director of the American Intellectual  Property Law Association (AIPLA), such a move would violate Article 27 of the Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) agreement, which says that all patents must run twenty years, regardless of the nature of the technology.  278  See supra note 121 and accompanying text.  279  Slind-Flor, supra note 119.  280  281  281  But while this may rule out shorter terms for software  Id. Id. See Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Final Act Embodying the Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations, 15 April 1994, Annex 1C, 33 I.L.M. 1197—stating that in all signatory countries, "patents shall be available and patent rights enjoyable without discrimination as to ... the field of technology."  Part V. Formulating  90  the Solutions  patents, precluding shorter terms for business methods depends on whether they are considered "technology" within the meaning of TRIPS. Although such a determination that has yet to be definitely resolved,  282  Professor Jay Thomas of George Washington University Law School makes a good case for  their exclusion: "At the time the United States entered into the TRIPS agreement, patents on business methods were not widely sought, and the common understanding among the patent bar was that the patentability of such methods was at best dubious. With the two other leading patent-granting powers, Europe and Japan, declining to award patents on methods of doing business, the more plausible reasoning is that business methods, like databases, lie without the TRIPS agreement."  283  3.  T H E BUSINESS M E T H O D P A T E N T I M P R O V E M E N T A C T  It didn't take long for the business method debate to find its way to Capitol Hill. On 2 October 2000, Representatives Howard'Berman (D-Calif.) and Frederick Boucher (D-Va.) introduced H.R. 5364, The Business Method Patent Improvement Act of 2000.  284  Citing the Amazon and Pricelihe patents  and their subsequent litigation, Rep. Boucher stated that their bill was meant to start a dialogue over patent law reform, and called on his colleagues to "repair the system before the P T O awards more monopoly power to people doing the patently obvious."  285  The first major provision of the proposed legislation laid out definitions for business methods and business method inventions. A business method was defined by the bill as administering, managing or otherwise operating an enterprise or organization, including techniques used in: (1) doing or conducting business; (2) processing financial data; (3) athletics; (4) instruction or personal skills; and  282  See Brian P. Biddinger, "Limiting the Business Method Patent: A Comparison and Proposed Alignment of European, Japanese and United States Patent Law" (2001) 69 Fordham L. Rev. 2523 at 2549.  2 8 3  John R. Thomas, "The Responsibility of the Rulemakcr: Comparative Approaches to Patent Administration Reform" (2002) at 24, Paper Presented to the Berkeley Center for Law & Technology Conference on Patent System Reform (1-2 March 2002: Berkeley, CA).  2 8 4  See Frackman & Stern, supra note 1 22.  Part V. Formulating  91  the Solutions  (5) any computer-assisted implementations thereof.  A business method invention was defined as any  invention that is a business method, including software or other apparatuses, and it appears the definition required' the business method to be covered by one or more claims.  The proposed  legislation also provided that the PTO would make a determination of whether an application discloses and claims a business method invention within 12 months after the earliest filing date of the application, from which an applicant would have 60 days to respond to the determination by amending or withdrawing the application.  286  Another key provision would have required all patent applications disclosing and claiming business method inventions to be published within 18 months from the earliest filing date. This would afford challengers the opportunity to mount pre-grant opposition to proposed patents, by either: (1) submitting prior art to the P T O , including evidence of knowledge or use, public use or sale; (2) filing a protest; or (3) petitioning the PTO to conduct a public use/on sale proceeding or consider whether the claimed invention is obvious under section 103.  287  This separate opposition procedure would be similar to reexamination in that any remarks and/or amendments submitted by the patent owner would entitle the third-party requestor to file, and have considered in the proceeding, their reply to the patent owner's statement. Moreover, under the proposed legislation, the opposition proceedings would be conducted as in court, including observing the Federal Rules of Evidence and allowing direct or cross- examination during the proceeding or in a deposition, affidavit or other documentary form, whether voluntary or compelled. The legislation also provided that claims could be amended at any time during the opposition proceeding, except that the scope of the claims could not be expanded. Further, the PTO would be required to render a decision as to the patentability of the subject matter of the patent within  2 8 i  Smith, supra note 108.  2 8 6  Sec Frackman & Stern, supra note 122.  287  Id.  92  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  18 months from the filing of the opposition request. Decisions resulting from opposition proceedings would be appealable to the Board of Patent Appeals and Interferences or to the applicable court, and either a patent owner or the third-party requestor could be a party to any such appeal taken. Upon termination, of the opposition proceeding or expiration of the time for appeal, a certification confirming patentable and/or unpatentable claims, and any claims that were canceled or added during the opposition proceeding, would be issued and published. To implement the opposition procedure, the Congressmen proposed establishing a separate administrative opposition panel.  288  Another, significant provision of the proposed legislation was a modification of the burden of proof requirementifor proving a business method application or patent invalid or otherwise ineligible. Congressmen Boucher and Berman proposed lowering the burden of proof required by a challenger to a "preponderance of the evidence" standard in a reexamination, interference, opposition, or other legal challenge to an application or patent.  289  Perhaps the most controversial of the Congressmen's proposals was an amendment to the nonobvious standard of section 103, establishing a rebuttable presumption that a business method invention is.obvious—i.e., the burden would fall upon applicants to establish by a preponderance of the evidence that a business method invention was not obvious. This amendment would only apply, however, to the fields of business methods and computer implementations, and thus would'effectively empower the patent examiners to reject, as obvious, applications which merely employ computer technology to carry out existing business methods.  290  The proposed legislation also attempted to address the inherent difficulties in locating relevant prior art for business methods.  It would have required the disclosure of any prior art searches  288  Id.  289  Id.  290  This proposal was reintroduced in the Business Methods Improvement Act of 2000—see infra note 321 and text.  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  93  conducted by business method patent applicants, and called for the PTO to establish appropriate penalties for failing to comply with this requirement. The Berman bill received a cool reception by many, if not most, of the U.S..patent bar. Of particular concern to many was the notion that the legislation would create a different process for approving one particular type of patent, thereby affording a great amount of special treatment to a body of subject matter that is not so unlike most other subject matter to be deserving of such treatment.  291  Even if enacted, most patent practitioners would likely take preventive steps during the  patent application drafting process in an attempt to avoid falling within the definition of business method invention, and the enhanced scrutiny that came with being so labeled.  ' •••••  292  Others criticized some of the provisions found in the proposed legislation as based upon misguided assumptions.. First, by narrowly targeting those patent applications in which the inventor merely adapted a well-known business activity to the Internet environment, the bill overlooks those applications outside the Internet realm—i.e., business methods implemented without the aid or use of a computer or other technology.  Furthermore, it appears that Congressman Berman misunderstood  the legal ^concept of nonobviousness under section 103.  He repeatedly stated that an invention is  unpatentable under that section if it would have been obvious to an expert in the field,  293  though the  proper standard for nonobviousness is whether it would have been obvious to one having ordinary skill in the art. Congressmen Berman and Boucher also encountered resistance from the legal community with regard to their proposal for lowering the burden of proof required to prove that a business method  291  Like shorter terms for business methods, this proposal was also (wrongly) criticized as running afoul of Article 27 of the TRIPS agreement—see supra.  2 9 2  This could be done by craftily drafting misleading invention descriptions set forth in the "Field Of The Invention" heading typically found in U.S. patent applications, which the USPTO relies upon, in addition to the claims, when selecting the U.S. Class in which the application should be classified. See Tim L. Brackett, Jr. & John Campa, "Legislating Patents on Business Methods" New York Law Journal(16 January 2001) at SS.  2 9 3  See 146 Cong. Rec. E 1659-60.  Part V. Formulating  94  the Solutions  application or patent is invalid or otherwise ineligible. Lowering the burden of proof standard would have contravened the judicially-forged "clear and convincing evidence" standard for proving a patent invalid.  In addition, this would have provided a defendant in an infringement suit another way to  attack a patent-in-suit by alleging that the patent should have been determined to be a business method during the PTO's examination and therefore subject to the lower standard. Finally, other critics have charged that as a practical matter, the limited resources of the PTO would be insufficient to effectively implement and support the infrastructure required to carry out the proposed legislation.  C.  294  Administrative Reform  While much of the proposed reform has been directed primarily at business method patents, a good portion of the debate has been focused on ways to improve patent quality generally.  As discussed  above, the social costs of improvidently-granted patents are numerous. Competitors may be forced to design around bad patents, or simply abandon their research activities, for fear of infringement; others may resolve to pay license fees instead of resorting to protracted litigation.  Consumers may be  required to pay supra-competitive prices in the absence of non-infringing product substitutes. Those who finance innovation may choose to invest in start-up companies based on bad patents, thereby taking away resources from genuine entrepreneurs.  Other parties may face duplicative, deal-killing  transaction costs when forced to revisit the work of the Patent Office in order to assess the validity of issued patents.  See Brackett & Campa, supra note 292. The Business Methods Improvement Act of 2000 was introduced so late in the last session of Congress that it died there, although a new version was apparently introduced earlier this year as the Business Methods Improvement Act of 2002, H.R. 1332. See Thomas, supra note 283, at 24. A search of Lexis-Nexis on 18 April 2002 turned up no other reference to the new bill, however, so I can't comment on any similarities or dissimilarities—though Thomas seems to suggest that it is substantially the same as H.R. 5364, and still has a slim chance of becoming law. Id.  Part V. Formulating  the  95  Solutions  This March, the Berkeley Technology Law Journal and the Berkeley Center for Law & Technology held yet another conference on patent reform. At this one, simply titled Patent System  Reform, some simple yet compelling solutions to the problem of bad patents were put forward by Professor Jay Kesan of the University of Illinois College of Law and Professor Jay Thomas of the George Washington University Law School.  1.  N E W PRIOR A R T DISCLOSURE SYSTEM  The root cause of bad patents, it seems, is that the PTO cannot accurately determine the scope of the prior art when examining patent applications, especially in areas such as computer software where the relevant prior art is hard to categorize or even find, and especially when the entire time spent by the Patent Office from initial examination to.patent issuance is a mere 18 hours.  295  In the first;strategy outlined by Professor Kesan, he suggests that we change our current prior art disclosure rules to create an option for applicants who wish to present an expanded information disclosure; statement. Those applicants who disclose all relevant prior art, plus an analysis of how the claims, as filed, are patentable over that prior art would be granted a specific presumption of validity with respect to the disclosed prior art, while those opting for regular disclosure would be denied any presumption of validity. Currently, a patentee has no duty to conduct an affirmative prior art search prior to filing a patent application—he need only disclose whatever prior art is in his possession.  296  Furthermore, the  list of prior art is submitted without any discussion of what the most important references in that list might be or how the claims are patentable over that prior art, and so the patent examiner has the  2 9 5  See Mark A. Lemley, "Rational Ignorance at the Patent Office" (2001) 95 Nw. L. Rev. 1495 at 1502.  2 9 6  See 37 C.F.R. § 1.56: "Each individual associated with the filing and prosecution of a patent application has a duty of candor and good faith in dealing with the Office, which includes a duty to disclose to the Office all information known to that individual to be material to patentability as defined in this section."  Part V. Formulating  96  the Solutions  unenviable task of discerning what relevant knowledge is buried in those references before she can assess the novelty or nonobviousness of the patent application. Despite the lack of information garnered from the patentee, however, the patent system grants a general presumption of validity to any issued patent,  297  and requires a challenger to produce "clear  and convincing" evidence of invalidity to overcome this presumption.  298  This is a Faustian bargain,  argues Kesan, because the public is essentially trading away its future right to invalidate a patent without receiving much knowledge in return.  Under his proposed system, the public would only  relinquish its residual invalidation rights upon receiving an expanded disclosure of the prior art which includes a discussion of how the claims, as filed, are patentable over it. Furthermore, the presumption of validity granted would be specific, not general—i.e., it would attach only to the disclosed prior art. For those patent applicants choosing not to provide the enhanced prior art disclosure, says Kesan, the public would retain all residual rights to invalidate the patent in post-issuance litigation and not grant any presumption of validity.  299  Such a system, he says, would benefit both the public and the patentee.  The public gains  because the PTO has better information with which to determine patent validity, thereby reducing the number of bad patents issued. The patentee's position is improved because he is granted a patent that  See 35 U.S.C. § 282: "A patent shall be presumed valid. Each claim of a patent ... shall be presumed valid independently of the validity of other claims..." Prior to 1982, in some circumstances a party could overcome the presumption of validity with a mere preponderance of the evidence, but in Connell v. Sears, 722 F.2d at 1549 (1983), the Federal Circuit ruled that "clear and convincing evidence" of invalidity must be put forth by the patent challenger before the court finds the PTO's decision of validity erroneous. In American  Hoist & Derrick  v. Sowa & Sons, 725 F.2d at 1359-60 (1984),  the court held that patents granted by the PTO are born valid and that the PTO's determination should be presumed to have been correct. In numerous cases since then, the court has continued to recite the clear and convincing evidence standard—see, e.g., Applied  Materials,  Inc. v. Advanced Semiconductor  Materials Am., Inc., 98 F.3d 1563  atl569(Fed. Cir. 1996); U.S. Surgical Corp. v. Ethicon, Inc., 103 F.3d 1554 at 1564 (Fed. Cir. 1997). Jay P. Kesan, "Carrots and Sticks to Create a Better Patent System," Paper Presented to the Berkeley Center for Law & Technology Conference on Patent System Reform (1-2 March 2002: Berkeley, CA) at 15. Though he doesn't suggest any standard to use instead, presumably the courts could fall back to the pre-Federal Circuit "preponderance of the evidence" standard, as was suggested for business method patents in the Business Method Patent Improvement Act of 2000, supra.  97  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  is less likely to be vulnerable in post-issuance litigation, thereby increasing its value to potential investors, shareholders, licensees and the like. And since the market will value these superior patent rights over those issued to applicants choosing the old disclosure system, there will be strong incentives to move to the new system. Kesan's proposals find support in a recent paper by Mark Lemley, who also participated in the Berkeley conference. "At a bare minimum," he says, "the presumption of validity should be pared back so that it covers only prior art references and.arguments actually considered by the examiner. There is simply no reason to defer to the examiner's purported decision on an issue the examiner did not even address."  300  evidence  Indeed, Lemley goes even further, suggesting that we eliminate the clear and convincing  requirement altogether,  making the presumption that a patent is rebuttable by a  preponderance of the evidence. "Based on what we know of patent examinations," he says, "deference •  4.  »301  is not appropriate..  2.  N E W FEE SHIFTING R E G I M E  One of Professor Kesan's other proposals is to expand fee shifting in patent cases.  302  Unlike the United  Kingdom and Canada, which operate under a two-way, loser-pays system, the United States, with a few exceptions, employs a pay-your-own-way legal system.  303  Section 285 of the U.S. patent statute  does allow a court in exceptional patent cases to grant reasonable attorney fees to the prevailing party, but in practice, the requirement of an "exceptional case" is extremely difficult to establish.  Lemley, supra note 295, at 1528-29. M a t 1529. Professor Kesan also suggests a third-party pre-grant opposition system and the use of representational languages in the specification of computer software patents—see supra note 299 at 16-31. The exceptions include the state courts of Alaska, Oklahoma, and Oregon, as well as plaintiffs winning federal civil rights trials. See Walter Olson & David Bernstein, "Loser-Pays: Where Next?" (1996) 55 Maryland L. Rev. 1161. 35 U.S.C. § 285. See Thomas D. Rowe, Jr., "The Legal Theory of Attorney Fee Shifting: A Critical Overview" [1982] Duke L.J. 651.  304  Part V. Formulating  98  the Solutions  In addition, by proving "willful infringement," patentees are far more likely to be awarded attorney's fees than accused infringers, whereas accused infringers won't usually get attorney's fees unless they can prove that the suit was filed in bad faith.  305  After discussing the merits of both American and British systems, Kesan proposes a one-way, pro-defendant fee shifting regime in which plaintiff patentees who have their patents invalidated or revoked in a.litigation or opposition proceeding by prior art that they should have discovered during a reasonable prior art search would have to pay all or part of the defendant's legal fees. Such asystem, he.says, should be effective at discouraging certain kinds of opportunistic conduct by increasing the costs for plaintiffs who choose to assert frivolous or invalid patents.  In addition, it would encourage,  patentees to conduct a thorough prior art search, both prior to filing for a patent and prior to enforcing a patent in court.  For defendants, it would create incentives to not settle prematurely and instead  continue with the litigation, especially if they believe their invalidation case is strong. This proposal also finds support from Lemley, who points out that in copyright law, the standards for prevailing parties seeking a fee award are identical whether the party is a plaintiff or a defendant. In the 1994 copyright case of Fogerty v. Fantasy, Inc., 106 the Supreme Court identified the important public policy interests in defending against unfounded copyright claims, and the result has been a dramatic rise in the number of fee awards in copyright cases. A similar rule in patent law, says Lemley, might help shift some of the burden in determining validity away from accused infringers.  See Great N. Corp.  v. Davis Core & Pad Co., Inc., 782 F.2d 159 (Fed. Cir. 1986) (holding that willful  infringement alone can make a case "exceptional" and therefore justify a fee award); Cambridge Prods., Ltd. v. Penn Nutrients,  Inc., 962 F.2d. 1048 at 1050-51 (Fed. Cir. 1992) ("In the case of awards to prevailing accused  infringers ... exceptional cases are normally those of bad faith litigation or those involving fraud or inequitable conduct by the patentee in procuring the patent.") 510 U.S. 517 at 527 (1994). Lemley, supranote  295, at 1531.  307  Part V. Formulating  3.  the  Solutions  99  OFFICIAL NOTICE  In his paper, "The Responsibility of the Rulemaker: Comparative Approaches to Patent Administration Reform," Professor Jay Thomas reviews the recent initiatives undertaken by the European Patent Office (EPO) and the JapanesePatent Office (JPO) and outlines several avenues for future reform of the U.S. Patent Office.  308  First and foremost, he suggests that to relieve the burden on the P T O ,  examination'burdens should continue to be shifted to patent applicants. He discusses two ways that this can be done cost effectively: the Patent Office should continue to make use of official notice where necessary, and it should mandate that drafters employ Jepson claims wherever possible. Like the concept of judicial notice, official notice substitutes for the usual process of proof via formal presentation of evidence. Under Federal Rule of Evidence 201, judicial notice may be taken of any adjudicative fact that is not subject to reasonable dispute because "it is capable of accurate and ready determination by resort to sources whose accuracy cannot reasonably be questioned."  309  The preferred  language is similar in patent procurement—PTO examiners may take official notice of such facts that "are capable of such instant and unquestionable demonstration as to defy dispute."  310  Although a fairly robust body of case law exists on the use of official notice, examiners have tended not to employ it very frequently.  311  Under standard PTO policy, if an applicant contests the  noticed fact, the examiner must then supply a reference demonstrating the fact, or else withdraw the rejection.  312  Thus, official notice has been little more than a delaying tactic that has detracted from the  general policy of timely prosecution.  308  Thomas, supra note 283.  3 0 9  F.R.E. 201(b).  310  In reAhlert,  311  See Lance L. Barry, "Did You Ever Notice? Official Notice in Rejections" (1999) 81 J. Pat. & Trademark Off. Soc'y  424 F.2d 1088 (CCPA 1970).  129. 312  Sec Patent & Trademark Office, Manual of Patent Examining Procedure § 2144.03 (7th ed. 1998).  Part V. Formulating  100  the Solutions  Professor Thomas points to accounts, however, that Class 7 0 S , that portion of the Patent Office responsible for reviewing business method applications, has begun to rely more heavily upon official notice.  Furthermore, Class 7 0 5 examiners are apparently less willing to withdraw rejections  founded upon official notice, even when applicants challenge the taking of notice. Thomas suggests that two cases from the Court of Customs and Patent Appeals (CCPA), the precursor to the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit, may underlie this recent phenomenon.  313  The first one, In re Howard, involved a patent application on an early version of bar coding—items were marked with a code that could be, used to supply retail prices at check-out via an "electrical comparison." claims:  314  On appeal, the CCPA used official notice to affirm the PTO's rejection of Howard's  "It is a matter of common practice of wide notoriety, well within the ambit of judicial  cognizance, for retail outlets to list by code or otherwise various items stocked for sale, together with the price assigned to each item, so as to enable the clerk or sales person to ascertain the charge to the customer. . . . [T]o electrically compare the code markings is without patentable significance."  315  According to Judge Almond, "patentability may not be predicated on the recitation of an electrical comparison.  »316  The CCPA took official notice one step further in In re Boon.  317  There, Boon had appealed  from the PTO's rejection of his application claiming a pneumatic conveyor system. Observing that the PTO Board had in part relied on official notice in affirming the examiner's rejection, Boon argued that he had not been given the chance to rebut the notice taking.  The court rejected that argument,  observing that Boon had either failed to challenge the notice taking at all, or had offered little more than an unsupported statement doing so.  3 1 3  See supra note 32.  3 , 4  394 F.2d 869 at 870 (CCPA 1968).  315  Id. at 870-871.  3 , 6  3 1 7  Id.  439 F.2d 724 (CCPA 1971).  The court then took the opportunity to stipulate that a  Part V. Formulating  the  101  Solutions  challenge to PTO notice must contain "adequate information of argument so that on its face it creates a reasonable doubt regarding the circumstances justifying the judicial notice."  318  Taken together, Howard and Boon suggest not only the lenient use of official notice in business method patent cases, but a substantial staying power for rejections founded upon official notice. Thus, the combination appears to provide the P T O with powerful tools for addressing applications claiming methods of doing business.  And, says Thomas, it appears that examiners are using them. Seemingly  cognizant of the criticisms surrounding business methods—in particular, the poor documentation;of prior art, the lack of scientific knowledge sharing, and the paucity of academic literature—the P T O "appears to have stealthily provided itself with a means to address applications in disciplines. where documentation is elusive."  319  Importantly, this tactic effectively preempts the approach taken by the Business Method Improvement Act of 2002, which, like its failed predecessor,  320  would create the presumption that a  claimed invention would have been obvious "if the only significant difference between the combined teachings of the prior art and the claimed invention is that the claimed invention is appropriate for use with a computer technology."  321  In effect, official notice achieves the same goal—placing upon  applicants the burden of proving that a computer-based business method presents an inventive advance over the prior art—but without running afoul of Article 27 of the TRIPS agreement, which arguably commands that business methods must be subject to the same standard of nonobviousness as all other technologies.  118  322  Id. at 728.  19  Thomas, supra note 283, at 24.  2 0  The Business Method Improvement Act of 2002, H.R. 1332, is the reintroduction of the Business Method Improvement Act of 2000, H.R. 5364, which died in the last session of Congress. See supra note 294.  21  22  Id., Section 5. As discussed above, it is questionable whether treating business methods differently would indeed violate the TRIPS agreement—but it is still unresolved. See supra notes 282-283 and accompanying text.  Part V. Formulating  102  the Solutions  Indeed, the heavily publicized Business Method Patent Initiative  already shows that the PTO  treats business method patent applications differently from others, but as Thomas points out, it can plausibly show that the distinctions it makes, under both that program and its use of official notice, are based upon the difficulty of examination rather than the discipline from which the claimed invention arises.  In support, the P T O could point to the W T O Dispute Settlement Body opinion in Canada —  Patent Protection of Pharmaceutical Products 31* whereby the W T O panel upheld the Canadian version of the Hatch-Waxman Act, despite its seemingly different treatment of pharmaceuticals. The express terms,of the Canadian statute applied to all regulated products, said the panel, so just because its effects were most keenly felt in the area of pharmaceuticals could not give rise to a finding of impermissible discrimination.  325  Thus, despite the TRIPS Agreement, administrators retain considerable discretion to address particular points of stress within the patent system, regardless of area of technology, so long.as the point of distinction is not one strictly based on a classification of that technology.  The use of official  notice provides a powerful tool for exercising that discretion, one that could efficiently  shift  examination burdens from patent offices to the private sector.  4.  JEPSON CLAIMS  Another way that foreign patent offices have eased their examination tasks is by encouraging the use of so-called "Jepson claims." A Jepson claim defines an invention in two parts. First, the preamble recites the subject matter of the invention and the technical features necessary to define the claimed subject, but that lie within the prior art. The second, or characterizing, portion of the claim states the technical  See supra, Section V.A.S.  WT/DS114/R (17 March 2000). Ibid, at para. 7.104.  Part V. Formulating  103  the Solutions  features that the patent adds to the prior art.  326  Both the EPO and the national patent offices of Europe  strongly encourage the use of the Jepson claim format,  327  and Patent Cooperation Treaty rules provide  that claims should be written in this style whenever possible.  328  In the United States, however, the patent bar has long derided the Jepson claim, primarily because the preamble of a Jepson claim constitutes an admission that the recited subject matter constitutes prior art. In addition, the Jepson claiming style tends to portray an invention as a limited improvement, rather than an elegant combination of diverse elements which together produce an inventive advance.  Yet while U.S. practitioners go to great lengths to avoid them, even redrafting  Jepson claims that they receive from their colleagues overseas, U.S. patent examiners generally prefer to receive such claims because they are far more readily parsed and compared to the prior art than other claim formats. Due to this advantage, Thomas suggests that the U.S. Patent Office should use its regulatory authority to compel applicants to use the Jepson claiming style wherever possible.  For support, he  points to the fact that the PTO has already required that claims be no more than one sentence long, and has barred the use of omnibus claims.  330  329  Such a change would provide another important  advantage—by conforming U.S. claiming practice with European and International trends, U.S. inventors would be in a better position for filing foreign patent applications.  Thomas, supra note 283, at 25. See Arthur L. Plevy, "Some Important Differences Between Patent Practice in Europe and the United States" Gune 2001) 209 N.J. Law 40 at 41 -42. PCT Rule 6.3. See Fressola v. Manbeck, 26 U.S.P.Q.2d 1211 (D.D.C. 1995). See Ex parte Fressola, 11 U.S.P.Q.2d 1608 (BPAI 1993).  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  S.  104  M O R E RESPONSIBILITIES F O R T H E H E A V I E S T USERS  In addition to shifting examination burdens to the private sector generally, via the use of official notice and Jepson claims, Professor Thomas suggests that we also increase the responsibilities of the heaviest users. It is no secret that a small number of companies dominate the U.S. patent system. Fourteen enterprises were awarded over one thousand patents in 2000, while an additional 151 companies obtained at least 100 patents.  331  Those 165 enterprises received a total of 56,105 patents—about  35.6% of the 157,497 utility patents granted that year. This "Century Club" of patent recipients has contributed significantly to the PTO's mounting workload, and holds disproportionate power with respect to It. Each member is in constant contact with the Patent Office, and enjoys a greater voice before the patent-oriented associations, such as the American Intellectual Property Association, the American Bar Association, and the Intellectual Property Owners, to which P T O management most closely listens.  Surely the Patent Office could justly turn to its heaviest users to address current  shortfalls. • • ••  Thomas points out that other patent offices have successfully imposed upon their frequently fliers before. Through its so-called "Action Plan for 80%" in 1992, the Japanese Patent Office made its best customers devote more time to the preparation of patent applications.  332  The approach taken by  the European Patent Office was less subtle—abandoning certain PCT commitments with regard to biotechnology, business method and telecommunications applications of U.S. origin—but was, nevertheless, a successful attempt at managing its workload by shutting its doors to the heaviest 333  users.  331  U.S. Patent & Trademark Office, Patenting by Organizations (2000).  332  In an effort to ease the task of examiners by presenting them with more applications that were already positioned for allowance, the JPO requested that large, domestic applicants endeavor to increase their individual allowance rate from approximately 60% to 80%. Among the steps applicants could take to reach the 80% plateau were conducting augmented prior art searches, requesting that few filed applications be examined, and, of course, making more selective filing decisions in the first place. See Thomas, supra note 283, at 17.  333  Id. at 28.  Part V. Formulating  105  the Solutions  Of course, varying applicant responsibilities based on their abilities is not a new idea in the United States either. The P T O fee schedule already allows for individual inventors, universities and small businesses to pay half the fees charged to their larger colleagues.  This approach, however,  merely subsidizes the patent expenses of smaller entities, without providing any real benefits to the Patent Office. The P T O should instead seize upon this concept as way of making its heaviest users assume additional patent examination responsibilities. Thomas suggests three ways that the P T O could make better use of its largest users.  First,  members of the "Century Club" should be compelled to perform initial prior art classifications and prior art searches with respect to their own applications, on behalf of the P T O and .under its supervision. Second, they should be expected to bring prosecution to a close promptly, with the PTO conducting periodic reviews of the status of each of their applications, with special attention paid to lingering applications from the pre-TRIPS era.  Finally, the P T O could mimic the Japanese Patent  Office's Action Plan for 80%, asking Century Club members to place their applications in a better position for timely examiner review.  D.  Doctrinal Reform  Let's now turn from the world of patent administration to the domain of judicial doctrine. As we've seen, the recent trend has been to bring more and more items within the scope of intellectual property protection, but without simultaneously re-assessing whether the doctrinal line between the protected and unprotected remains appropriately situated.  Historically, the patent system has assumed that  market incentives will, more often than not, lead patentees to exploit their innovations efficiently, often by licensing them to others in the field.  Licensing helps to realize patent law's goals both by  increasing the probability that the public will benefit from the invention before the patent's expiration, and by encouraging follow-on innovation by licensees and others who purchase the patented product.  Part V. Formulating  the Solutions  106  While market defects may have at times frustrated the conclusion of socially-beneficial agreements, until recently, the system has functioned in a reasonably efficient manner. Patentees were unlikely to suppress their innovations by refusing to license them, or to use their patents to leverage whatever market power they possessed into secondary markets. In today's world, however, these traditional assumptions have proven incorrect. In the market for operating systems software, strong patent protection has created insurmountable barriers to entry and allowed a few patentees to direct innovation toward applications running on the dominant system. In other industries, the rapid issuance of patents has resulted in an "anti-commons," where rights are held by so many different patentees that the costs for any one to accumulate all the required licenses is prohibitive. In' existing law, a number of doctrines act to limit the scope of the patent right and ameliorate these problems: the experimental use doctrine, the reverse doctrine of equivalents, and the doctrines of patent misuse, exhaustion, and implied license. Given the current problems with the patent system, a number of commentators have called for these to be expanded or modified, or for some new doctrines to be added. A failure to do so, warns one, would be regrettable: "The risk is that, in the absence of a doctrine that permits some privilege of unlicensed use while at the same time protecting patentees' incentives, the patent system may function to thwart the very innovation it is intended to  1.  EXPERIMENTAL USE  In her groundbreaking 1987 paper, University of Michigan Law Professor Rebecca Eisenberg examined the effect of strengthened intellectual property rights on scientific research, particularly in the  Maureen A. O'Rourke, "Toward a Doctrine of Fair Use in Patent Law" (2000) 100 Colum. L. Rev. 1177 at 1180.  Part V. Formulating  107  the Solutions  emerging field of biotechnology.  335  Arguing that the enforcement  of exclusive  rights against  subsequent researchers can sometimes interfere with further progress in the field of the invention, she called for an expansion of the experimental use defense to patent infringement. The experimental use defense first appeared in dictum in the 1813 case of Whittemore v.  Cutter." 6 In his decision, Justice Story observed that "it could never have been the intention of the legislature to punish a man, who constructed a [patented] machine merely for philosophical experiments, or for the purpose of ascertaining the sufficiency of the machine to produce its described; effects." ' Although subsequent courts have consistently recognized the existence of an experimental 337  use defense in theory, the defense has almost never succeeded in practice, mostly because the courts have held that it does not apply to the facts of the particular cases before them.  338  Modern case law suggests that the experimental use defense is available only for "pure" research with no commercial implications.  In Roche Products v. Bohr Pharmaceutical Co., the  Federal Circuit rejected the argument of a drug manufacturer that the defense applied to its use of the plaintiffs patented drug in performing clinical tests, the purpose of which was to gather data necessary to obtain FDA approval so that the defendant could market a generic version of the drug as soon as the patent expired.  339  Characterizing the experimental use defense as "truly narrow," the court noted that  Rebecca S. Eisenberg, "Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights and Experimental Use" (1989) 56 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1017. 29 F. Cas. 1120 ( C C D . Mass. 1813). Id. at 1121.  Northill  Co. v. Danforth,  51 F. Supp. 928 at 929 (N.D. Cal. 1942) ("Defendant's experiments were evidently not  made for philosophical or amusement purposes but were made in connection with his business as a manufacturer and salesman of anchors"); Sprout, Waldron & Co. v. Bauer Bros. Co., 26 F. Supp. 162 at 169 (S.D. Ohio 1938) ("The defendant cannot escape on the ground of experimental use where the machines were used to operate upon customers' products in the ordinary course of business"); R.C.A.  v. Andrea, 15 F. Supp. 685 at 687 (E.D. N.Y.  1936), mod'd on other grounds, 90 F. 2d 612 (2d Cir. 1937) (assembling parts of patented combination to test them was infringement where assembly was "not a scientific research or an engineering inquiry" but rather "a step which the defendants apparently deemed necessary in the manufacture and sale of their product"). 733 F.2d 858 (Fed. Cir. 1984).  108  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  the defendant's use of the drug was "no dilettante affair such as Justice Story envisioned."  The court  340  held that the defense does not permit "unlicensed experiments conducted with a view to the adoption: of the patented invention to the experimentor's business," as opposed to experiments conducted "for amusement, to satisfy idle curiosity, or for strictly philosophical inquiry."  341  In her paper, Eisenberg asserts that this formulation of the experimental use defense is indeed too narrowband should be expanded to cover certain circumstances. First, use of a patented invention for the purpose of verifying the adequacy of the specification and the validity of the patentee's claimsshould be exempt from infringement liability. Such access would serve both the interests of;science ;  and the policies• underlying the patent system itself, namely, that the patentee make an enabling disclosure. Justice Story highlighted the importance of this interest in introducing the experimental use doctrine in Whittemore v. Cutter, noting that it should not constitute patent infringement to construct a patented machine "for the purpose of ascertaining the sufficiency of the machine to produce the desired effects."  342  It is not at all clear that such a use would not constitute infringement today under  the standard laid down by the Federal Circuit in Roche.  343  340  Id at 863.  341  Id. Congress has since abrogated the rule of Roche insofar as it pertains to generic drug manufacturers, but left the experimental use aspect of the decision intact. 35 U.S.C. § 271(e).  3 4 2  2 9 F. Cas. at 1121. See also Sawin v. Guild, 21 F. Cas. 554 at 555 ( C C D . Mass. 1813) (noting that the making of a patented machine "to ascertain the verity and exactness of the specification" should not constitute infringement).  3 4 3  Other intellectual property statutes provide broader experimental use exemptions. See, e.g., Plant Variety Protection Act of 1970, 7 U.S.C. § 2544 (1982) ("The use and reproduction of a protected variety for plant breeding or other bona fide research shall not constitute an infringement of the protection provided under this • chapter"); Semiconductor Chip Protection Act of 1984, 17 U.S.C. § 906(a) (Supp. 1986) (exempting from infringement liability the reproduction of a protected work "solely for the purpose of teaching, analyzing, or evaluating the concepts or techniques" embodied therein or the creation of an original work incorporating the . results of such analysis or evaluation). The patent laws of many other countries, including Japan and most members of the European Economic Community, recognize an experimental use exemption that is not limited to specific fields of technology. See Stephen A. Bent, et al., Intellectual Property Rights in Biotechnology Worldwide 342-45, citing European Community Patent Convention, Art. 31(b) (which provides that patent protection shall not extend to "acts done for experimental purposes relating to the subject-matter of the patented invention".) See also Japanese Patent Law of 1978, Art. 69(1).  Part V. Formulating  the  Solutions  109  More importantly, proposes Eisenberg, an expanded experimental use defense could provide a solution to those situations where a failure to license patented technologies may be blocking scientific progress.  As is especially true with cutting-edge technologies, it is often in the best interests of a  patentee to seek injunctions against subsequent research in the same field, especially if the research threatens to.render the patented invention obsolete.  Even if the parties can agree to negotiate, a  number of things may prevent them from concluding a license.  344  First, uncertainty or disagreement as  to the value of the patented invention, the likely outcome of the research project, and the validity and scope of the patent claims might make it difficult for the parties to agree on a price for a license. Itmight.be possible to work around some of these problems through a license agreement which conditions royalty obligations on detailed contingencies, but negotiating the terms of such a license could be costly and burdensome; for research projects requiring access to many different••• patented inventions, such transaction costs could become insurmountable. Second, if the subsequent researcher and the patent holder are research rivals, the subsequent researcher might be reluctant to disclose valuable research plans to the patent holder in the course of negotiations for fear that the patent holder will pursue the research plans itself rather than extend a license to the researcher. In either situation, if the research is to proceed at all, it would have to be without the patentee's permission, and thus under the threat of injunction.  Eisenberg argues, therefore, the experimental use defense be used to prevent the granting of injunctions against subsequent research use of a patented invention—that is, a patentee would be prevented from enjoining research which could potentially lead to improvements in the patented technology or the development of alternative means of achieving the same purpose.  Yet while a  research exemption in this context may be necessary in order for valuable research to proceed, Eisenberg realizes that allowing researchers to avoid all liability to the patent holder would restrict the  Eisenberg, supra note 335, at 1073-74.  Part V. Formulating  the  110  Solutions  value of the patent monopoly and therefore reduce patent incentives, in two ways.  345  First, it deprives  the patent holder of royalties that might otherwise be collected from researchers. Second, by lowering, the cost to< competitors of inventing around the patent, it shortens the expected duration of the patentee's effective monopoly. Depending on the circumstances, Eisenberg proposes a court-imposed solution to the problem in the form of an ex ante award of damages for the research use.  346  If, on the one hand, the subsequent  researcher used the patented invention to invent around the patent, developing a new technology that may be exploited without infringing the patent claims, the patent holder has no means of extracting / payment'from the researcher at the commercial exploitation stage, and therefore denying a remedy for the research use would undermine the value of the patent monopoly and lead to unjust enrichment of the researcher. In this situation, suggests Eisenberg, the court would require the researcher to pay a reasonable royalty to the patent holder in order to ensure that the patent holder is adequately compensated for the use of the patented invention. On the other hand, if the original patent is broad enough in scope to cover the improved technology developed by the researcher, the court need not step in. In that situation, the interests of the patent holder will be adequately protected by traditional enforcement of the patent—i.e., the patentee can sue for royalties on the sale of the infringing product if the infringer fails to negotiate a license.  Given, however, that overbroad patents and the failure to  effectively license are the problems it is attempting to solve, Eisenberg's experimental use solution comes up short in such a situation.  While she fails to address it, subsequent commentators have  proposed more refined solutions, one of the most notable of which is Maureen O'Rourke's proposal for a fair use defense.  345  Id. at 1075-76.  346  Id. at 1076-77.  111  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  2.  FAIR USE  Like the experimental use defense and reverse doctrine of equivalents in patent law, the fair use defense is a long-standing equitable doctrine that attempts to fine-tune the scope of copyright law.  347  In effect, a fair use defense imposes a limited royalty-free license on the copyright owner—the party asserting the defense has infringed, but the infringement is excused. Its rationale is similar to that of its patent law counterparts, namely, that market failures may sometimes justify labeling an infringing use as fair if it is socially desirable and excusing it will not substantially harm the copyright owner's incentives. In some cases, particularly those involving parody, the market failure may be the refusal of the copyright owner to grant a license at any price.  348  In others, high transaction costs may frustrate  private bargaining, as was the case when the Supreme Court refused to enjoin Sony from selling VCRs on the basis that consumers would face insurmountable transaction costs in identifying, contacting and contracting with the individual copyright owners for permission to tape their television broadcasts.  349  Using copyright fair use as her model, Professor O'Rourke performs a critical examination of current patent law doctrine to identify what gaps might be filled by a patent fair use defense.  350  Under  the current reverse doctrine of equivalents, infringement is justified when the infringer makes a radical improvement to the patented invention, the probability of bargaining breakdown is high, and society would bear large costs if the new invention were kept from it. ' This suggests, says O'Rourke, that a 35  comprehensive fair use doctrine should consider the nature of the advance that the infringing work  3 4 7  348  The doctrine existed at common law long before its codification in the 1976 Copyright Act: 17 U.S.C. § 17 (1994). See, e.g., Campbell v. AculF-Rose Music, S10 U.S. 569 at 572-73 (1994) (allowing a fair use defense where the parodist had sought permission from copyright owner to use copyrighted work and offered to pay, but copyright owner refused, stating, "I must inform you that we cannot permit the use of a parody of 'Oh, Pretty Woman'").  349  Sony Corp. ofAmerica v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 4-64- U.S. 417 (1984).  3 5 0  O'Rourke, supra note 334, at 1202.  351  See Scripps Clinic & Research Found, v. Genentech, Inc., 921 F.2d 1565 at 1581 (Fed. Cir. 1991) (suggesting that a literally infringing device may nonetheless escape liability under the reverse doctrine of equivalents because it is a radical improvement on the patented technology). The reverse doctrine of equivalents is similar to the doctrine of equivalents, except that while the former excuses infringement, the latterfindsit.  Part V. Formulating  the  112  Solutions  represents, with major advances weighing in favour of the infringer.  352  Excusing infringement under  the current experimental use exception is highly unlikely to impact the patentee's incentives because the infringer's purpose is merely to satisfy his or her own "amusement." This suggests that a fair use defense should consider whether the purpose of the infringement is commercial or not.  353  Here she highlights the shortcomings of Professor Eisenberg's proposal for a modified experimental use defense—that it inadequately deals with the situation in which a researcher develops an improvement that is within the scope of the patented invention and is unable to negotiate a license for i t .  While this result, concedes O'Rourke, may generally be justified to maintain the original  354  patentee's incentives, there may be cases where society would benefit from allowing the infringement to continue. A fair use defense should therefore consider whether market defects exist that frustrate the licensing of improvements. It should then balance the impact on the patentee's incentives if the infringement were excused against the increase in social welfare if the improvement were made available.  355  Building on work by Professor Donald Chisum regarding the patentability of algorithms and the concern that patenting such fundamental building blocks may impede further progress if no use is privileged, O'Rourke concludes that a fair use defense should also take into account the nature of the invention.  356  All patented inventions, she reasons, are not created equal; follow-on innovators have  more need to make an infringing use of some inventions than others. Professor O'Rourke's analysis thereby identifies five factors relevant to a finding of fair use: (1) the nature of the advance represented by the infringement; (2) the purpose of the infringing use; (3) the nature and strength of the market failure that prevents a license from being concluded; (4) the  3 5 2  3 5 3  3 5 4  3 5 5  356  O'Rourke, supra note 334, at 1203 Id. Id. at 1204. Id.  Id. at 1205—citing Donald S. Chisum, "The Patentability of Algorithms" (1986) 47 U. Pitt. L. Rev. 959 at 1017.  Part V. Formulating  113  the Solutions  impact of the use on the patentee's incentives and overall social welfare; and (5) the nature of the patented work.  Faced with a case of patent infringement, a court could use this five-part test to  determine whether to excuse a use as fair. As in copyright, no one factor would be determinative and fair use would be an equitable and affirmative defense with the burden of proof on the infringer.  357  O'Rourke's construction of a fair use framework doesn't stop with the five-part consideration, however.  She adds a final piece of flexibility in the form of a royalty determination.  If the court  decides that the infringement is fair, it should then consider whether or not the infringer • should compensate the patentee.  358  As with copyright fair use, some uses will justify a "free" fair use—  namely, situations where high transaction costs prevent private bargaining or where the infringing use is socially beneficial but the infringer simply cannot pay the price. Educational and other non-profit uses like pure research would fall into this category. After applying her fair use test to a number of concrete examples, Professor O'Rourke devotes a large part of her paper to addressing possible criticisms. Chief among these is that modifications to existing doctrines and to the workings of the P T O should be able solve the problems that the fair use defense is attempting to remedy.  359  Why implement a broad new doctrine that has the potential, to  further complicate the administration of patent law? She gives two persuasive reasons. First, a case-by-case adjustment of doctrine, either through statutory changes or common law adjudication, is likely to be more expensive than a fair use doctrine that would be enacted only once. Whether changes occur incrementally or through the introduction of fair use, costs will increase for a time as parties and courts struggle to understand the new rules, but a fair use approach should prove cheaper than a number of discrete changes because courts will have copyright precedent from which to draw by analogy. In addition, fair use has the flexibility to tailor  " Id. at 1209.  3  358  359  Id. Id. at 1242.  114  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  rights across a broad spectrum of industries. Correcting quirks in the patent system and counteracting PTO errors would be benefits incidental to fair use's main purpose of providing a unifying yet flexible concept under which courts could address a range of market failures in a number of distinct contexts. Furthermore, those market defects all share similar characteristics.  The anti-patent motives  that can frustrate competition in a network market may also lead patentees to refuse licenses toresearchers'Seeking to verify functionality. High transaction costs, strategic bargaining, and bargaining, breakdown are universal phenomena not restricted to particular technologies or non-commercial contexts, and therefore they require an integrated approach. Rather than being overbroad, fair use is a 'flexible approach to a common problem. •  ;  !•  O'Rourke anticipates another more theoretical criticism. By allowing courts the discretion of. imposing a fee, the patent system may start down a slippery slope that transforms the traditional right to exclude into a liability rule where all uses are fair, and the only issue is setting the appropriate royalty. At.its.heart, responds O'Rourke, this objection goes to judicial competence in applying the new doctrine. Applied correctly, patent fair use would excuse only those infringements that pass the a five-factor test. The ability to award a fee is an insurance policy against unduly reducing the patentee'sincentives, not an invitation to the judiciary to reform patent law into a liability regime.  360  That the judiciary will occasionally err and that patentees and the public will bear the costs of those errors is inevitable, but that is not a condition unique to fair use nor a sufficient reason to oppose its implementation. In fact, argues O'Rourke, because the Federal Circuit is generally the exclusive forum for hearing.patent appeals, the chances for incorrect precedent are somewhat lower for patent fair use than under the already existing copyright scheme.  Id. at 1243.  361  Indeed, "because the defense is broadly  Part V. Formulating  the  115  Solutions  applicable to market failures across a spectrum of industries, its costs of implementation should, at least as its application becomes more predictable, be offset by its benefits."  362  3.  REVERSE ENGINEERING  In another recent paper, Julie Cohen and Mark Lemley call for a slightly different approach.  363  Like  Eisenberg and O'Rourke, they find that the traditional doctrines are inadequately equipped to address the problems now facing patent law, but they focus their solutions more specifically at the software industry.  In particular, they advocate a limited right to "reverse engineer" patented computer  programs in order to gain access to their unprotected elements.  364  Since computer software was traditionally protected by trade secret and copyright law, such reverse engineering was a commonplace occurrence. It is clearly legal under trade secret law,  365  and  while there is no express statutory provision in copyright permitting reverse engineering, its fair use doctrine has been the basis for numerous court decisions which have allowed it.  366  The recent migration of computer software into the realm of patent protection, however, threatens to eliminate this important right. The patent statute includes no express provision allowing  3 6 2  3 6 3  3 6 4  Id. at 1249.  Julie Cohen & Mark Lemley, "Patent Scope and Innovation in the Software Industry" (2001) 89 Calif. L. Rev. 1. ' Reverse engineering of software, also called "decompilation," involves working backwards from object code to produce a simulacrum of the original source code. See Andrew Johnson-Laird, "Software Reverse Engineering in the Real World" (1994) 19 U. Dayton L. Rev. 843.  365  See, e.g., Unif. Trade Secrets Act 1, cmt, 14 U.L.A. 438-39 (1990); Chicago Lock Co. v. Fanberg, 676 F.2d 400 (9th Cir. 1982); Restatement of Torts at 757 cmt. f (1939); Restatement (Third) Unfair Competition at 43 (1995).  366  Primarily, reverse engineering has been held lawful when used for laudable competitive purposes, such as producing new works that compete with the copyrighted original, producing products for downstream markets that are compatible with the copyrighted original, and obtaining access to uncopyrighted ideas, facts, or other material "locked up" within a copyrighted work. See, e.g., Bateman v. Mnemonics,  Inc., 79 F.3d 1532 (11th Cir. 1996)  (endorsing the use of reverse engineering to gain access to the unprotectable ideas in a program, as well as access to copyrighted expression that might be used fairly); Sega Enters. Ltd. v. Accolade,  Inc., 977 F.2d 1510 (9th Cir.  1992) (holding that reverse engineering was lawful where necessary to make an independently created video game work with the plaintiffs game system).  Part V. Formulating  the  116  Solutions  reverse engineering, nor is there any judicially-developed exception akin to copyright's fair use doctrine that might permit it.  Since reverse engineering of a patented computer program almost  certainly constitutes an infringing activity under current patent law,  367  some sort of defense must be  created in order to save it. Cohen and Lemley point to a number of important reasons why this is crucial.  368  First, the  patent system in premised on others having adequate access to patented inventions so that they can improve on them. Some inventions, such as the paper clip, are readily apparent once embodied in a product, but software inventions cannot be improved upon without having access to a much more detailed description. In theory, the disclosure requirements of section 112 are supposed to provide, this, but recent Federal Circuit decisions have held that software patentees need not disclose source code, object code, or even flowcharts, but only a high-level functional description.  369  As a result, there  is often no way to figure out a piece of patented software without reverse engineering it. Second, reverse engineering is often necessary to obtain access to unpatented components. While some software patents cover an entire computer program, the majority cover only a single part of a program, perhaps a particular algorithm or subroutine, or even a process for getting from one stage to another. If reverse engineering is illegal, then patenting even a small part of one computer program can give the patentee effective control over all the ideas contained in the program. Indeed, claim Cohen and Lemley, patentees have periodically taken advantage of this fact by patenting "lock-  3 6 7  While owners of a particular copy of computer program may have the right to "use" it under the doctrines of exhaustion and implied license, decompilation usually involves generating a temporary copy in RAM memory— and, in certain instances, a longer-term copy in more permanent memory—and therefore likely constitutes an unauthorized "making" of the patented program. Cohen & Lemley, supra note 363, at 9.  368  3 6 9  Id. at 23-28. See Fonar Corp. v. General Electric Co., 107 F. 3d 1543 at 1549 (Fed. Cir. 1997). The Federal Circuit reasons that "the conversion of a complete thought ... into a language a machine understands is necessarily a mere clerical function to a skilled programmer." Northern  Telecom,  Inc. v. Datapoint  Corp., 908 F.2d 931 at 941 -42 (Fed. Cir.  1990)—quoting In re Sherwood, 613 F.2d 809 at 817 (1980). Indeed, the court has gone so far as to hold that patentees can satisfy the best mode requirement for inventions implemented in software even though they do not use the terms "computer" or "software" anywhere in the specification. Robotic 42 U.S.P.Q.2d 1619 (Fed. Cir. 1997).  Vision Sys., Inc. v. ViewEng'g,  Inc.,  117  Part V. Formulating the Solutions  out" devices and using the patent to try to deny access to the unpatented components of specialpurpose operating systems.  370  Third, because patent, copyright, and trade secret rights can coexist simultaneously in the same piece of software, intellectual property policy for software must be made with that combination of rights in mind. If the courts conclude that patent law does not permit reverse engineering, they will have effectively nullified its allowance in copyright and trade secret law.  The absurdity of such a,  contradiction was demonstrated vividly in a recent case involving Sony, whereby the computer maker  ;  is attempting an end-run around the Ninth Circuit decision by filing a software patent infringement suit, against the same act of reverse engineering that the court held legal under copyright law.  371  Finally, and more than a little ironically, a ban on reverse engineering might make it difficult or even impossible to detect patent infringement. Since many software inventions are internal to the program and their use cannot be detected without inspecting the code, a patent owner who suspects a rival of infringing such a software patent may have no choice but to reverse engineer the rival's software in order-to gain the evidence needed to file suit. If that rival has its own patents on a separate aspect of the program, however, reverse engineering as part of a pre-filing investigation will infringe its own patents. At the least, this puts a new argument in the hands of a patent defendant; at most, it may deter valid patent infringement suits from ever being filed. Cohen and Lemley go on to survey the various defenses to patent infringement to show that none of them properly protects the right to reverse engineer software.  372  Looking first to the  experimental use exception, they note that Rebecca Eisenberg's proposal for a broader interpretation would protect reverse engineering, and recommend that the courts read the defense as she suggests. As currently construed, however, the experimental use defense is too narrow.  3 7 0  See, e.g., Atari Games Corp. v. Nintendo ofAmerica, Inc., 97S F.2d 832 at 843-44 (Fed. Cir. 1992).  371  Sony ComputerEntm't, Inc. v. Connectix Corp., 203 F.3d 596 (9th Cir. 2000).  3 7 2  Cohen & Lemley, supra note 363, at 29-36.  Part V. Formulating  118  the Solutions  The authors then turn to the well-established principle that a patentee's right to control the use of his patented goods does not extend beyond the first sale—i.e., a consumer who buys a patented product from the patentee has the right to use and resell that product without the patentee's approval.  373  Courts have developed two parallel doctrines in support of this principle: exhaustion and  implied license. Both doctrines have traditionally drawn a distinction between using and reselling a particular copy of a patented product, which is permissible, and making a new copy of a patented product, which is not. Software patents undermine this distinction, however, because it is impossible to use software without "making" a copy, at least temporarily, in the memory of a computer.  374  If the exhaustion and  implied license doctrines do not protect the making of such temporary copies, they will be effectively nullified in the software context, with the consequence that no use of a purchased program would be permissible without express permission from the patentee. While Cohen and Lemley think that a reasonable court would reject such an interpretation, 1  they raise the concern that patentees might be able to override the protection of the exhaustion and implied license doctrines by conditioning the sale or license of the patented product on an agreement not to reverse engineer it. doctrine,  373  375  Though such an action would likely run afoul of the patent misuse  they would rather see Congress create a specific statutory right to reverse engineer  Glass Equip. Dev. v. Besten, Inc., SO U.S.P.Q.2d 1300 (Fed. Cir. 1999) ("Thefirstsale doctrine stands for the proposition that, absent unusual circumstances, courts infer that a patent owner has given up the right to exclude concerning a patented article that the owner sells."); Becton, Dickinson & Co. v. Eisele & Co., 86 F.2d 267 at 270 (6th Cir. 1936) ("Once having sold patented articles, neither the patentee nor its licensee may exercise future control over them. They pass beyond the scope of the patentee's monopoly.").  3 7 4  This has been the subject of considerable litigation in the copyright arena. Most courts now hold that a temporary copy loaded in the RAM memory of a computer is "fixed" and therefore constitutes a new copy for copyright purposes. See, e.g., MAISys.  Corp. v. Peak Computer,  Inc., 991 F.2d S11 at S18 (9th Cir. 1993). While this is  almost certainly the wrong conclusion, an analogousfindingin patent laws is almost assured. Because patent law has nofixationrequirement at all, any reproduction of a patented program, no matter how temporary, arguably constitutes a "making" within the meaning of the statute. 3 7 5  Patent misuse is an equitable defense to patent infringement that precludes patentees from "impermissibly broadening the 'physical or temporal scope' of the patent grant with anticompetitive effect." B. Braun Med., Inc. v. Abbot Labs., 124 F.3d 1419 at 1426 (Fed. Cir. 1997)—quoting Windsurfing  Int'l, Inc. v. AMF, Inc., 782 F.2d 99S  Part V. Formulating  the  119  Solutions  patented software, as has already been done in both the Semiconductor Chip Protection Act Digital Millennium Copyright Act. outlined will be up to the task.  377  and the  Barring that, they hope that the doctrinal adjustments they have  "While we think that existing law, properly interpreted, can and  should protect reverse engineering for legitimate purposes, Congress could easily guarantee such a right if the courts fail to do so."  378  at 1001-02 (Fed. Cir. 1986). If it is determined that a patentee has engaged in misuse, he will be prevented from enforcing his patent at all, at least until the misuse has been purged. 17 U.S.C. § 906(a) (1994). 17 U.S.C.A. § 1201(f) (1996 & Supp. 2000). Cohen & Lemley, supra note 363, at 36.  120  Part VI.  Conclusion  VI.  CONCLUSION  So it seems that in the complex new economy of the twenty-first century, the classic incentive theory of the patent system no longer tells the whole story. Once patently simple, the relationship between patents and innovation is now much harder to discern. A controversial annexation of foreign subject matter, an exponential growth in patent applications and issuances, and a significant relaxation of judicial constraints have stretched the system to the breaking point. But is the patent system really in crisis? Much has changed in the nearly two years since research on this thesis began, and I've moved from critiquing the patent system from the outside to working within it. Whether this has caused me to modify, or mollify, my perspective is uncertain, but it does seem that the system is working better today, that the concerns are abating somewhat.  Critics  like Robert Merges seem more optimistic. One year after peppering his commentary with words like "crisis" and "breakdown,"  379  he devotes an essay to the thesis that "intellectual property law has  generally adapted quite well to each successive wave of technological innovation."  380  Indeed, there is evidence that the courts have become better at assessing the novelty and nonobviousness  of the new inventions.  Communications decision.  381  Encouraging in this regard is the AT&T  v. Excel  In the first incarnation of that case, the Federal Circuit held AT&T's  telephone billing method patentable as a business method. In a later phase, however, the patent was invalidated as obvious in light of MCI's "Friends and Family" long-distance program. And in February of last year, in the appeal of the Amazon.com case, the Federal Circuit removed the preliminary injunction that had been granted against Barnes & Noble.  382  The court found that because Amazon's  "1-Click" patent claims were not confined to the Internet, the relevant prior art could also not be  3 7 9  Merges, supra note 187.  3 8 0  Merges, supra note 37, at 2190.  3 8 1  AT&T  Corp. v. Excel Communications,  supra note 20.  Part VI.  121  Conclusion  limited to Internet applications. Since Barnes & Noble had demonstrated, with reference to such prior art—in particular, a mid-1990s stock-chart system—that there was a substantial question as to the nonobviousness of Amazon's patent, the injunction was vacated.  383  Yet while the courts may be getting better at limiting the scope of bad patents, shouldn't the emphasis be on preventing them in the first place? Again, the focus comes around to the U.S. Patent & Trademark Office. Despite its best efforts, is the PTO doing a good enough job at examining patents? Do they have the resources they need? As Charles Baker, chair of the Intellectual Property Law Section of the ABA, suggests, the patent system would best be served by appropriations rather than legislation. "If Congress is truly concerned about avoiding PTO delays and ensuring good patents, they should give the PTO the money it needs. . . . The office does not have as many examiners as it should have to issue quality patents in a reasonable time."  384  Baker's complaint seems to carry recent weight on Capitol Hill.  This spring, the Bush  administration proposed boosting Patent Office funding by 21 percent and imposing a one-time patent application surcharge of 19 percent, a move that would generate an additional $45 million for the agency and $ 162 million for the rest of the government.  385  But is fixing the PTO really the cure? Picking up on his "missing patents" theme, Mark Lemley suggests that because the overwhelming majority of patented inventions are not used in ways that call their • validity into question, we're better off focusing on the few cases where a patent is actually licensed or litigated. The title of his recent paper, "Rational Ignorance at the Patent Office," invokes economic jargon for the proposition that the PTO should remain "rationally ignorant" of the objective  12  Amazon.com  v. Barnesandnoblc.com,  239 F.3d 1343 (Fed. Cir. 2001).  13  Unfortunately, it took fourteen months and the passing of two holiday shopping seasons for it to happen.  14  Smith, supra note 108.  15  Andy Sullivan, "Kids beware: Playground swing now patented" Yahoo!News(18  April 2002).  Part VI.  122  Conclusion  validity of patents because the cost of acquiring the information necessary to make perfect patentability judgments far exceeds the benefits.  386  Estimating that about $20,000 is spent taking the average patent from initial application to issuance, and working with recent data indicating that 28.4% of the 275,000 patent applications filed in the year 2000 were continuation applications, which may only cost around $5,000, Lemley calculates; that domestic patent prosecution costs a total of $4.33 billion per year.  387  He then calculates the total amount spent on litigation and licensing.  Using an AIPLA report  that the median cost of patent litigation to each side is $799,000 through the end of discovery and $ 1,503,000 through trial and appeal,  388  together with data indicating that around 1,600 patent cases are  filed each year, but only about one hundred of those actually make it to trial, annual amount spent on litigation at $2.1 billion.  390  389  Lemley gauges the total  He notes that this total is only the cost of legal  fees—-it does not include the costs of judgments paid, nor does it include the indirect social costs such . as judicial resources or the time lost by corporate employees involved in the case.  3 8 6  3 8 7  388  Lemley, supra note 295. Id. at 1499.  These numbers are the same as reported in Section 1V.D, supra. The average cost of patent litigation is likely higher (i.e., $2.1 million) because some extremely expensive cases will raise the average above the median. The AIPLA study does report that the seventy-fifth percentile of patent cases cost $ 1,503,000 to take through discovery and $2,510,000 through the end of the case. AIPLA Report of Economic Survey (of U.S. IP Practitioners) (1999)— cited in Craig P. Opperman, "Computer Technology Patents (With an Emphasis on Internet & E-Commerce Related Patents)" (2000) 590 PLI/Pat 1039 at 1047.  3 8 9  Like Lerner and Lanjouw, supra, Lemley cites the Derwent database for the number of cases filed. Lemley, supra note 295, at 1502. For the number of cases that go to trial, however, he cites Kimberly Moore, "Judges, Juries and Patent Cases: Empirical Evidence to Peek Inside the Black Box" (2000) 99 Mich. L. Rev. 365 (stating that the number of trials per year from 1988 to 1998 ranged from a low of 86 to a high of 108). These numbers don't match well with Lerner and Lanjouw's calculations that about 670 cases go to trial, but, using their assumptions, the total cost of litigation is about the same—see note 390, infra.  3 9 0  Lemley arrives at this number by calculating the total cost of those suits that are filed but settled beforehand ($799,000 x 1,500 cases x 2 parties = $2.4 billion) but discounting that by 25% to account for the fact that some cases will settle early in the litigation process and not incur full discovery costs. To this $1.8 billion he adds the costs of those cases which go to trial ($1,503,000 x 100 cases x 2 parties = $301 million) to arrive at $2.1 billion. Lemley, ibid. If we use Lerner and Lanjouw'sfindingthat about 600 cases go to trial, that would add $1.8 billion instead of $301 million, but those authors found that most cases that don't go to court settle quite early on the  Part VI.  123  Conclusion  Lemley also calculates the cost of licensing outside of litigation, using the estimate that the total number of patents either litigated or licensed for a royalty is on the order of five percent of issued patents. Since 1.5% are litigated, that leaves 3.5% licensed, or about 5250 patents, each of which costs an estimated $100,000 to license, for a total of $525 million.  Adding to that the total spent on  litigation, his final total for litigation and licensing costs rises to $2.62 billion.  391  What does he use all these numbers for? To test the cost effectiveness of various administrative reforms. First, he looks at the common proposal that more time should be spent examining patents, perhaps double the 18 hours spent currently. This wouldn't double the cost of prosecution, since much of the cost is incurred in drafting the initial application, but it might mean a 50% increase in the costs of prosecution, he assumes, from an average of $20,000 per original application to $30,000. Because more time is being spent on each patent, the number of patents issued should then drop. The size of the drop is hard to estimate, Lemley admits, and will "depend on the quality of the patents that currently issue and how many of the bad patents that currently issue can be smoked out merely by adding a few more hours to an examiner's evaluation."  392  Assuming that the total number of issued patents would drop by approximately ten percent as a result of truly final rejections of more applications, and taking into account that a more comprehensive examination process should deter some people from filing applications at all, Lemley projects that the number of applications would stop its significant upward trend and fall by about ten percent.  393  Thus, the total costs of prosecution under the double-examination system would be  177,200 original applications at $30,000 ($5.2  billion), plus 70,300 continuing prosecution  litigation process, so let's discount those cases ($2.4 billion) by 75% to arrive at a figure of $600 million. Adding the $1.8 billion gives us roughly the same total: $2.4 billion vs. $2.1 billion. 391  3 9 2  3 9 3  Id. atlS09. Id.  To clarify, deterrence would stop the upward trend in applications, and more rejections would reduce current issuances by approximately 10%.  Part VI.  124  Conclusion  applications at $7,500 per patent ($530 million), for a total cost of $5.85 billion—an increase of $1.52 billion in the cost of prosecution.  394  But how much would this save out of the $2.62 billion spent on litigation and licensing? Assuming again that about ten percent of bad patents would be prevented from issuing, litigation and licensing costs should also drop by 10%, or $262 million. So we would be spending $1.52 billion to attain a benefit of $260 million—hardly an efficient use of resources. Lemley also considers the proposal that patent applicants conduct a prior art search before? filing their applications and to disclose the results of that search to the P T O . Pricing prior art searches somewhere between $5,000 and $7,000, depending on the complexity of the technology and how crowded the field is, and accounting for additional legal expenses, Lemley estimates that-such a proposal would add between $8,000 and $10,000 to the cost of patent prosecution.  395  If we; assume  the same results as for doubling examination time, the cost-benefit structure remains unchanged— an expenditure five times the benefit. Lemley admits that his conclusion depends crucially on the fact that very few patents are ever the subject of litigation or licensing, but rejects the notion that it is dependant on the assumptions he< makes. Indeed, he spends a considerable amount of time examining his estimates and assumptions, and asserts that even if his assumptions were relaxed "beyond all reasonable bounds, the fundamental fact remains that litigation of a few patents is a far more efficient way of determining validity that giving a detailed ex ante examination to all patents."  396  So even accounting for Lemley's estimates, it's hard to avoid the conclusion that money is better spent on the back-end of the patent system—in litigation. But how? As mentioned above, he endorses the idea that the presumption of validity granted to issued patents should be lowered or even  3 9 4  3 9 5  396  Id. Id. at IS 10. Id. at 1514.  Part VI.  125  Conclusion  dropped altogether, and he also thinks that some expansion of fee shifting is a good idea. Those are good suggestions for litigation reform, but as Jay Thomas points out, we shouldn't abandon the PTO as a focus of reform either. We just need to look to solutions that improve the quality of issued patents without incurring significant costs, such as making use of official notice, mandating the use of Jepson claims, and placing more responsibility on the heaviest users. The proposals for doctrinal reform also hold great promise, especially Maureen O'Rourke's suggestion that patent law adopt a fair use defense modeled on copyright. Her five-factor test with an optional royalty: award is a disciplined yet flexible approach to the problem of overbroad patents and the failure to license them. In addition, it would also allow for the.right to reverse engineer patented programs and devices, as proposed by Julie Cohen and Mark Lemley. Solutions could also come from outside the system. Tim O'Reilly's open letter to Jeff Bezos,  398  397  In November 2000, nine months after  the pair joined other investors in launching BountyQuest,  an online company that offers rewards to anyone who can find prior art on certain patents. BountyQuest has offered rewards ranging from $10,000 to $40,000 for prior art on several controversial new patents, including Priceline.corn's reverse auction, SightSound's Digital Download technology, and Double Click'_s_ banner advertising method, and even Amazon's 1-Click patent. Indeed, BountyQuest went so far as to offer a reward for information undermining its own patent on "an Internet-based, broadcast reward service for finding prior art relevant to the validity of a patent."  399  In January 2001, BountyQuest announced its first four $10,000 winners, whose findings undermined the validity of a method of online music sampling, a way to control access to an event venue, and to single-chip network routers. And on 14 March 2001, it announced the results of the  3 9 7  See Cohen & Lemley, supra note 363, at 37: "Some commentators have suggested that patent law should include a general fair use right; if it did, that right would certainly encompass the limited protections for reverse engineering we suggest here."  3 9 8  See supra note 120 and accompanying text.  399  Smith, supra note 108.  Part VI.  126  Conclusion  challenge to Amazon's 1-Click patent. BountyQuest receiving 30 submissions for the posting, and "while we didn't have an exact-match winner, we found prior art that closely matched every claim in the patent," said O'Reilly.  400  "These submissions clearly demonstrate the power of the Internet when  it's used as a networking tool, instead of as a traditional search engine. BountyQuest ensures that a wider community of voices are heard when patent validity is in question."  401  The idea of patent bounties appears to have currency among academics. In another recent article, Professor Thomas proposes that the Patent Office usurp the role of BountyQuest, employing a class of private patent examiners who would research and disclose patent-defeating  references.  '"Employing private citizens as partners in patent examination," he submits, "offers a fiscally realizable solution for restoring order to our patent system and ultimately lowering its social costs."  402  In the end, whether the patent system is considered to be in a state of crisis or not, there are enough stakeholders convinced that the current level of resources committed to the patent system is excessive, that surely there must be ways in which costs, delays, and uncertainties can be substantially reduced. Substantive change will remain difficult—especially given the failure to demonstrate many real effects of the policy program so far, and thus predict the results of any future direction—but some sort of change is inevitable. What form it will take remains to be seen, but one thing is certain: the past twenty years of patent reform will not be the last.  "BountyQuest Unveils Results of Challenge to Amazon.com 1 - Click Patent" Business Wire (14 March 2001). Id.  John R. Thomas, "Collusion and Collective Action in Patent System: A Proposal for Patent Bounties" [2001] U. 111. L. Rev. 305 at 353.  References  127  REFERENCES  Adelman, Martin J. "The New World of Patents Created by the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit" (1987) 20 U . Mich. J.L. Ref. 979. Arup, Christopher. Innovation, Policy andLaw (Cambridge, 1993). Ayres, Ian & Paul Klemperer. "Limiting Patentees' Market Power without Reducing Innovation Incentives: The Perverse Benefits of Uncertainty and Non-Injunctive Remedies" (1999) 97 Mich. L. Rev. 985. Azure, Anthony H . "Festo's Effect on After-Arising Technology and the Doctrine of Equivalents" (2001) 76 Wash. L. Rev. 1153. Bagby, John W . "Business Method Patent Proliferation: Convergence of Transactional Analytics and Technical Scientifics" (2000) 56 Bus. Law. 423. Bagley, Margo A. "Internet Business Model Patents: Obvious by Analogy" (2001) 7 Mich. Telecomm. Tech. L. Rev. 253. Barta, James J., Jr. "Death of a Superior Intellectual Property Law System" (1998) 17 St. Louis U . Pub. I.. Rev. 383. Barton, John H . "Reforming the Patent System" (17 March 2000) Science 1933. Bartow, Ann. "Separating Marketing Innovation from Actual Invention: A Proposal for a New, Improved, Lighter, and Better-Tasting Form of Patent Protection" (2000) 4 J. Small & Emerging Bus. L. 1. Bauz, N . Thane. "Reanimating U.S. Patent Reexamination: Recommendations for Change Based Upon a Comparative Study of German Law" (1994) 27 Creighton L. Rev. 945. Biddinger, Brian P. "Limiting the Business Method Patent: A Comparison and Proposed Alignment of European, Japanese and United States Patent Law" (2001) 69 Fordham L. Rev. 2523. Blair, Roger D. 8c Thomas F. Cotter. "An Economic Analysis of Damages Rules in Intellectual Property Law" (1998) 39 W m . and Mary L. Rev. 1585. Boss, Aimee. "The Twenty-First Century Patent System Improvement Act: Is It Really An Improvement?" (1999) 32 J. Marshall L. Rev. 725.  References  128  Burke, Thomas P. "Software Patent Protection: Debugging the Current System" (1994) 69 Notre Dame L. Rev. 1115. Burr, J. Beckwith. "Competition Policy and Intellectual Property in the Information Age" (1996) 41 Vill. L. Rev. 193. Calandrillo, Steve P. "An Economic Analysis of Intellectual Property Rights: Justifications and Problems of Exclusive Rights, Incentives to Generate Information, and the Alternative of a Government-Run Reward System" (1998) 9 Fordham I.P., Media & Ent. L.J. 301. Chiappetta, Vincent. "Defining the Proper Scope of Internet Patents: If We Don't Know Where We . Want to Go, We're Unlikely to Get There" (2001) 7 Mich. Telecomm. Tech. L. Rev. 289. Cohen, Julie E. "Reverse Engineering and the Rise of Electronic Vigilantism: Intellectual Property Implications of 'Lock-Out' Programs" (1995) 68 S. Cal. L. Rev. 1091. Cohen, Julie E. 8c Mark A. Lemley. "Patent Scope and Innovation in the Software Industry" (2001) .89 Calif. L. Rev. 1. Corcoran, Peter. "The Scope of Claim Amendments, Prosecution History Estoppel, and the Doctrine of Equivalents after Festo VI" (2001) 9 Tex. Intell. Prop. L.J. 159. Costello, Pat. "New Law Creates a Patent Infringement Defense and Restructures the Patent and Trademark Office" (2000) 6 B.U. J. Sci. 8c Tech. L. 16. Dam, Kenneth W . "Some Economic Considerations in the Intellectual Property Protection of : Software" (1995) 24 J. Legal Stud. 321. Davis, Michael D. "The Patenting of Products of Nature" (1995) 21 Rutgers Computer & Tech. L.J. 293. Dawson, Gwendolyn. "Matchmaking in the Realm of Patents: A Call for the Marriage of Patent Theory and Claim Construction Procedure" (2001) 79 Tex. L. Rev. 1257. Dreyfuss, Rochelle C . "Licensee Estoppel and the Incentive to Innovate" (1986) 72 Va. L. Rev. 677. . "Are Business Method Patents Bad for Business?" (2000) 16 Computer 8c High Tech. L.J. 263. . "An Alert to the Intellectual Property Bar: The Hague Judgments Convention" [2001] U . 111. L. Rev. 421.  129  References  Duke, Jeffrey P. "The First Inventors Defense Act (35 U.S.C. § 273): Have Prior User Rights in Patent Law Been Resurrected?" (2001) 20 St. Louis U . Pub. L. Rev. 223. Eisenberg, Rebecca S. "Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights and Experimental Use" (1987) 56 U . Chi. L. Rev. 1017. . "Analyze This: A Law and Economics Agenda for the Patent System" (2000) 53 Vand. L. Rev. : 2081. Epstein, Richard A. "Intellectual Property: Old Boundaries and New Frontiers" (2001) 76 Ind. L.J. 803.  /  Fisk, Catherine L. "Removing the 'Fuel of Interest' from the 'Fire of Genius': Law and the EmployeeInventor,T830-1930" (1998) 65 U . Chi. L. Rev. 1127. Flores Troy, Edwin S. "The Development of Modern Frameworks for Patent Protection: Mexico, a Model for Reform" (1998) 6 Tex. Intell. Prop. L.J. 133/ Freidman, Aryeh S. "Law and the Innovative Process: Preliminary Reflections" [1986] Colum. Bus. L.-Rcv 1.  . The Law of High Technology Innovation (Butterworth, 1992). Frischmann, Brett. "Innovation and Institutions: Rethinking the Economics of U.S. Science and Technology Policy" (2000) 24 Vt. L. Rev. 347. Frischmann, Brett & Dan Moylan. "The Evolving Common Law Doctrine of Copyright Misuse: A Unified Theory and Its Application to Software" (2000) 15 Berkeley Tech. L.J. 865. Gabay, Sari. "The Patentability of Electronic Commerce Business Systems in the Aftermath of State  Street Bank & Trust Co. v. Signature Financial Group, Inc." (1999) 8 J.L. & Pol'y 179. Goldstein, Paul. "Comments on 'A Manifesto Concerning the Legal Protection of Computer Programs'" (1994) 94 Colum. L. Rev. 2573. Gordon, Wendy J. "Assertive Modesty: An Economics of Intangibles" (1994) 94 Colum. L. Rev. 2579. Gorma, Robert A. "Comments on 'A Manifesto Concerning the Legal Protection of Computer Programs'" (1996) 5 Alb. L.J. Sci. 8c Tech. 277.  References  130  Graham, Lawrence D . & Richard O. Zerbe, Jr. "Economically Efficient Treatment of Computer Software: Reverse Engineering, Protection, and Disclosure" (1996) 22 Rutgers Computer & Tech. L.J. 61. Haldiman, Robert C . "Prior User Rights for Business Method Patents" (2001) 20 St. Louis U . Pub. L. Rev. 245. Hattenbach, Benjamin. "On Illuminating Black Hole in Patent Disclosures: Toward a Structured Approach to Identifying Omitted Elements Under the Written Description Requirement of Patent Law" (2001) 38 Hous. L. Rev. 1195. Haynes, Mark A. "Commentary: Black Holes of Innovation In the Software Arts" (1999) 14 Berkeley Tech. L.J. 567. Hubert, Pierre Jean. "The Prior User Right of H.R. 400: A Careful Balancing of Competing Interests" (1998) 14 Computer & High Tech. L.J. 189. Hughes, Justin. "The Philosophy of Intellectual Property" (1988) 77 Geo. L.J. 287. Jackman, Peter A. "Adoption of First-to-File Patent System: A Proposal" (1997) 26 U . Bait. L. Rev. 67. Janis, Mark D. "Rethinking Reexamination: Toward a Viable Administrative Revocation System for U.S. Patent Law" (1997) 11 Harv. J. Law 8c Tech. 1. . "Second Tier Patent Protection" (2000) 40 Harv. Int'l L.J. 151. :  "Patent Law in the Age of the Invisible Supreme Court" [2001] U . 111. L. Rev. 387.  Johnson-Laird, Andy. "Looking Forward, Legislating Backward?" (2000) 4 J. Small & Emerging Bus. L. 95. Kahin, Brian. "The Expansion of the Patent System: Politics and Political Economy" (January 2001)  First Monday. Kalan, K. "Property Rights, Individual Rights, and the Viability of Patent Law Systems" (2000) 71 U . Colo. L. Rev. 1439. Karp, Jordan P. "Experimental Use as Patent Infringement: The Impropriety of a Broad Exception" (1991) 100 Yale L.J. 2169.  References  131  Kastenmeier, Robert W . & Michael J. Remington. "The Semiconductor Chip Protection Act of 1984: A Swamp or Firm Ground?" (1985) 70 Minn. L. Rev. 417. Katopis, Chris J. "Patients v. Patents?: Policy Implications of Recent Patent Legislation" (1997) 71 St. John's L. Rev. 329. . "The Federal Circuit's Forgotten Lessons?: Annealing New Forms of Intellectual Property Through Consolidated Appellate Jurisdiction" (1999) 32 J. Marshall L. Rev. 581. Kesan, Jay P. & Thomas S. Ulen. "Foreword: Intellectual Property Challenges in the Next Century" [2001] U . 111. L. Rev. 57. Kidwell, John A. "Software and Semiconductors: Why Are We Confused?" (1985) 70 Minn. L. Rev. 533. Kieff, Scott F. "Intellectual Property Rights and the Norms of Science—A Response to Rai and Eisenberg" (2001) 96 Nw. U . L . Rev. 691. Kingston, William. Innovation, Creativity and Law (Kluwer Academic, 1990). Kitagawa, Zentaro. "Comments on 'A Manifesto Concerning the Legal Protection of Computer Programs'" (1994) 94 Colum. L. Rev. 2610. Kobak, James B., Jr. "Intellectual Property, Competition Law and Hidden Choices Between Original and Sequential Innovation" (1998) 3 Va. J.L. 8c Tech. 6. Krause, William. "Sweeping the E-Commerce Patent Minefield: The Need for a Workable Business Method Exception" (2000) 24 Puget Sound L. Rev. 79. Kreiss, Robert A. "Patent Protection for Computer Programs and Mathematical Algorithms: The Constitutional Limitations on Patentable Subject Matter" (1999) 9 N . M . L. Rev. 31. Kryger, William T. "The Doctrine of Equivalents into the Year 2000: The Line Is Becoming Brighter for Some but Remains Dim for Others" (1999) 3 Marq. Intell. Prop. L. Rev. 203. Kuester, Jeffrey R. 8c Lawrence E. Thompson. "Risks Associated with Restricting Business Method and E-Commerce Patents" (2001) 17 Ga. St. U . L . Rev. 657. Landis, James E. "Amazon.com: A Look at Patenting Computer Implemented Business Methods Following State Streef (2001) 2 N . C . J.L. 8c Tech. 1.  References  132  Lando, Peter R . "Business Method Patents: Update Post State Streef (2001) 9 Tex. Intell. Prop. L . J . 403. Lemley, Mark A . "The Economic Irrationality of the Patent Misuse Doctrine" (1990) 78 Calif. L . Rev. 1599. . "The Economics of Improvement i n Intellectual Property Law" (1997) 75 Tex. L . Rev. 989. . "Beyond Preemption: The Law and Policy of Intellectual Property Licensing" (1999) 87 Calif. L . Rev. 111. . "Reconceiving Patents in the Age of Venture Capital" (2000) 4 J . Small 8c Emerging Bus. L . 137. . "Rational Ignorance at the Patent Office" (2001) 95 N w . L . Rev. 1495. • Lemley, Mark A . 8c John R . Allison. " H o w Federal Circuit Judges Vote in Patent Validity Cases" (2000) 2 9 F . S . U . L . Rev. 745. . "Who's Patenting What? A n Empirical Exploration of Patent Prosecution" (2000) 53 Vand. L . Rev. 2099. Lemley, Mark A . 8c Lawrence Lessig. "The End of End-to-End: Preserving the Architecture of the Internet in the Broadband Era" (2001) 48 U C L A L . Rev. 925. Lemley, Mark A . 8c David M c G o w a n . "Legal Implications of N e t w o r k Economic Effects" (1998) 86 Calif. L . Rev. 479. Lemley, Mark A . 8c David W . O ' B r i e n . "Encouraging Software Reuse" (1997) 49 Stan. L . Rev. 255. Lerner, Josh. "Patent Policy Innovations: A Clinical Examination" (2000) 53 Vand. L . Rev. 1841. Lichtman, Douglas, Scott Baker 8c Kate Kraus. "Strategic Disclosure in the Patent System" (2000) 53 Vand. L . Rev. 2175. Linck, Nancy J . , Kevin T . Kramer 8c David J . Ball, Jr. " A N e w Patent Examination System for the N e w Millennium" (1998) 35 Hous. L . Rev. 305. Littman, Allan N . "Restoring the Balance of O u r Patent System" (1997) 37 I D E A 545. Long, Doris Estelle. "First, 'Let's K i l l all the Intellectual Property Lawyers!': Musings on the Decline and Fall of the Intellectual Property Empire" (2001) 34 J . Marshall L . Rev. 851.  References  133  Lunney, Glynn S., Jr. "E-Obviousness" (2001) 7 Mich. Telecomm. Tech. L. Rev. 363. McGowan, David. "Free Contracting, Fair Competition, and Article 2B: Some Reflections on Federal Competition Policy, Information Transactions, and 'Aggressive Neutrality'" (1998) 13 Berkeley Tech. L.J. 1173. . "Legal Implications of Open-Source Software" [2001] U . 111. L. Rev. 241. Machin, Nathan. "Prospective Utility: A New Interpretation of the Utility Requirement of Section 101 of the Patent Act" (1999) 87 Calif. L. Rev. 421. Marchese, Christopher S. "Promoting the Progress of the Useful Arts by Narrowing Best Mode Disclosure Requirement in Patent Law" (1993) 54 U . Pitt. L. Rev. 589. Marks," Colin P. "Opening the Door to Business Methods: State Street Bank & Trust Co. v. Signature  Financial Group, Inc." (2000) 37 Hous. L. Rev. 923. Maskus, Keith E. "Lessons From Studying the International Economics of Intellectual Property Rights" (2000) S3 Vand. L. Rev. 2219. Mauk, JohnE. "The Slippery Slope of Secrecy: Why Patent Law Preempts Reverse-Engineering" (2001) 43 W m . and Mary L. Rev. 819. Maurer, Erik S. "An Economic Justification for a Broad Interpretation of Patentable Subject Matter" (2001) 95 Nw. U . L . Rev. 1057. Menell, Peter S. "The Challenges of Reforming Intellectual Property Protection for Computer Software" (1994) 94 Colum. L. Rev. 2644. Merges, Robert P. "Commercial Success and Patent Standards: Perspectives on Innovation" (1988) 76 Calif. L. Rev. 803. . "Intellectual Property Rights and Bargaining Breakdown: The Case of Blocking Patents" (1994) 62 Tenn. L. Rev. 75. . "Of Property Rules, Coase, and Intellectual Property" (1994) 94 Colum. L. Rev. 2655. . "The Law and Economics of Employee Inventions" (1999) 13 Harv. J. Law & Tech. 1.  References  134  . "Who Owns the Charles River Bridge? Intellectual Property and Competition in the Software Industry" (1999) Working Paper, available at http://www.law.berkeley.edu/library/BPL/bplvol3.html. . "As Many as Six Impossible Patents Before Breakfast: Property Rights for Business Concepts and Patent System Reform" (1999) 14 Berkeley Tech. L.J. 577. . "One Hundred Years of Solicitude: Intellectual Property Law, 1900-2000" (2000) 88 Calif. L. Rev. 2187. . "Intellectual Property Rights and the New Institutional Economics" (2000) 53 Vand. L. Rev. 1857. Merges, Robert P. 8c Richard R. Nelson. "On'the Complex Economics of Patent Scope" (1990) 90 Colum. L. Rev. 839. Merges, Robert P. 8c Glenn H . Reynolds. "The Proper Scope of Copyright and Patent Power" (2000) Harv. J. on Legis. 45. Metcalfe, Susan V. "Protecting Trade Secrets: Is the Remedy Worse than the Wrong?" (2000) 104 Dick. L. Rev. 503. Mossoff, Adam. "Rethinking the Development of Patents: An Intellectual History, 1550-1800" (2001) 52 Hastings L.J. 1255. Nard, Craig A. "Deference, Defiance, and the Useful Arts" (1995) 56 Ohio St. L.J. 1415.  r  : "Certainty, Fence Building, and the Useful Arts" (1999) 74 Ind. L.J. 759.  O'Rourke, Maureen A. "Rethinking Remedies at the Intersection of Intellectual Property and Contract: Toward a Unified Body of Law" (1997) 82 Iowa L. Rev. 1137. . "Fencing Cyberspace: Drawing Borders in a Virtual World" (1998) 82 Minn. L. Rev. 609. . "Progressing Towards a Uniform Commercial Code for Electronic Commerce or Racing Towards Nonuniformity?" (1999) 14 Berkeley Tech. L.J. 635. . "Evaluating Mistakes in Intellectual Property Law: Configuring the System to Account for Imperfection" (2000) 4 J. Small 8c Emerging Bus. L. 167. . "Toward a Doctrine of Fair Use in Patent Law" (2000) 100 Colum. L. Rev. 1177.  135  References  Okediji, Ruth. "Givers, Takers, and Other Kinds of Users: A Fair Use Doctrine for Cyberspace" (2001) 53 Fla. L. Rev. 107. Paley, Mark A. "A Model Software Petite Patent Act" (1996) 12 Computer & High Tech. L.J. 301. Rai, Arti K. "Regulating Scientific Research: Intellectual Property Rights and the Norms of Science" (1999) 94 Nw. U . L . Rev. 77. . "Addressing the Patent Gold Rush: The Role of Deference to PTO Patent Denials" (2000) 2 Wash. U . J.L. & Pol'y 199. . "The Information Revolution Reaches Pharmaceuticals: Balancing Innovation Incentives, Cost, and Access in the Post-Genomics Era" [2001] U . 111. L. Rev. 173. Reichman, J.H. "Legal Hybrids Between the Patent and Copyright Paradigms" (1994) 94 Colum. L. Rev. 1501. Rhodes, Kevin. "The Federal Circuit's Patent Nonobviousness Standards: Theoretical Perspectives on Recent Doctrinal Changes" (1991) 85 Nw. U . L . Rev. 1051. Robertson, Jeffrey E. "If It Ain't Broke, Don't Fix It: The Unnecessary Scope of Patent Reform as Embodied in the 21 Century Patent System Improvement Act and The Omnibus Patent Act of st  1997" (1998) 5 J. Intell. Prop. L. 573. Samuelson,^. Pamela A. "Benson Revisited: The Case Against Patent Protection for Algorithms and Other Computer-Related Inventions" (1990) 39 Emory L.J. 1025. Samuelson, Pamela A . , Randall Davis, Mitchell D. Kapor, c i J.H. Reichman. "A Manifesto Concerning the Legal Protection of Computer Programs" (1994) 94 Colum. L. Rev. 2308. Samuelson, Pamela A. 8c Randall Davis. "The Digital Dilemma: A Perspective on Intellectual Property in the Information Age" (2000) Presented at the 28 Annual Telecommunications Policy Research th  Conference, available on-line at http://www.sims.berkeley.edu/~pam/papers.html. Schaffner, Joan E. "Patent Preemption Unlocked" [1995] Wis. L. Rev. 1081. Schainholz, Jay D . "The Validity of Patents after Market Testing: A New and Improved Experimental Use Doctrine?" (1985) 85 Colum. L. Rev. 371. Schallop, Michael J. "The IPR Paradox: Leveraging Intellectual Property Rights to Encourage Interoperability in the Network Computer Age" (2000) 28 AIPLA Q.J. 195.  136  References  Schlicher, John W . Patent Law: LegalandEconomic  Principles (Clark Boardman Callaghan, 1993).  Selinger, Jerry R. "In Defense of 'Best Mode': Preserving the Benefit of the Bargain for the Public" (1994) 43 Cath. U . L . Rev. 1071. Shavell, Steven & Tanguy Van Ypersele. "Rewards versus Intellectual Property Rights " (2001) 44 J. Law & Econ. 525. Slayton, Nicole-Marie. "Internet Business Model Patents: An Obvious Incentive to Reform the United States Patent and Trademark Office" (2000) 21 Loy. L.A. Ent. L.J. 123. Smith, Len S. "Promoting the Progress of Science and America's Small Entity Inventors: Inventing an Improved U.S. Patent Application Publication Provision Out of the Prior Art" (1999) 77 Wash. U . L.Q.585. Soobert, Allan M . "Breaking New Grounds in Administrative Revocation of U.S. Patents: A Proposition for Opposition — and Beyond" (1998) 14 Computer & High Tech. L.J. 63. Stern, Richard H . "Scope-of-Protection Problems With Patents and Copyrights on Methods of Doing Business" (1999) 10 Fordham L P . , Media & Ent. L.J. 105. Takenaka, Toshiko. "Commentary: International and Comparative Law Perspectives on Internet Patents" (2001) 7 Mich. Telecomm. Tech. L. Rev. 423. Thomas, John R. "The Patenting of the Liberal Professions" (1999) 40 B.C. L. Rev. 1139. . "The Post-Industrial Patent System" (1999) 10 Fordham L P . , Media 8c Ent. L.J. 3. . "On Preparatory Texts and Proprietary Technologies: The Place of Prosecution Histories in Patent Claim Interpretation" (1999) 47 U C L A L. Rev. 183. . "Collusion and Collective Action in Patent System: A Proposal for Patent Bounties" [2001] U . 111. L. Rev. 305. Torche, Mark D. "Rubber Stamp of Court of Last Resort: The Proper Standard of Review in Patent and Trademark Cases" (1999) 48 Drake L. Rev. 211. Wagner, Dana R. "The Keepers of the Gates: Intellectual Property, Antitrust, and the Regulatory Implications of Systems Technology" (2000) 51 Hastings L.J. 1073. Walter, Carrie F. "Beyond the Harvard Mouse: Current Patent Practice and the Necessity of Clear Guidelines in Biotechnology Patent Law" (1998) 73 Ind. L.J. 1025.  References  137  Watson, Mark B. "Expansion, Compression and Relief: An Analysis of the Jury's Role in Patent Infringement Cases Employing the Doctrine of Equivalents" (1996) 2 Roger Williams U . L. Rev. 91. Wells, Matthew G. "Internet Business Method Patent Policy" (2001) 87 Va. L. Rev. 729. Wright, Jacqueline D . "Implications of Recent Patent Law Changes on Biotechnology Research and the Biotechnology Industry" (1997) 1 Va. J.L. 8c Tech. 2. Zimmerman, William M . "Unifying Markman and Warner-Jenkinson: A Revised Approach to the Doctrine of Equivalents" (1997) 11 Harv. J. Law 8c Tech. 185.  Economics Articles Bessen, James 8c Eric Maskin. "Intellectual Property on the Internet: What's Wrong with Conventional Wisdom?" (1997), available on-line at http://ksgwww.harvard.edu/iip/econ/bessen.html. . "Sequential Innovation, Patents, and Imitation" (January 2000) Working Paper No. 00-01, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, available on-line at http://www.researchoninnovation.org/patent.pdf. Cohen, Wesley M . , Richard R. Nelson 8c John P. Walsh. "Protecting Their Intellectual Assets: Appropriability Conditions and Why U.S. Manufacturing Firms Patent (or Not)" (2000) National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper No. W7552, available on-line at http:// papers. nber. org / papers / W75 5 2. De Long, J. Bradford & A. Michael Froomkin. "The Next Economy?" (April 1997), available on-line at http: / / www. law .miami. edu/ ~froomkin/articles/newecon .htm. . "Speculative Microeconomics for Tomorrow's Economy" (November 1999), available on-line at http: / / personal. law. miami .edu/ ~froomkin/articles/ spec.htm. Hall, B.H. 8c. R. Ham Ziedonis. "The Patent Paradox Revisited: An Empirical Study of Patenting in the U.S. Semiconductor Industry, 1979-95" (2000) Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley. Hunt, Robert. "Patent Reform: A Mixed Blessing for the U.S. Economy?" (Nov./Dec. 1999) Federal  Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review.  References  138  . "Nonobviousness and the Incentive to Innovate: An Economic Analysis of Intellectual Property Reform" (March 1999) Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper, available on-line at http: / /www.phil.frb.org/files/wps/1999/wp99-3 .pdf. Irlam, Gordon & Ross Williams. "Negative Correlation of Innovation and Software Patents" (January 1994) Revised version of Appendix D of the League for Programming Freedom's submission to the U.S. Patent Office, available on-line at http://www.base.com/software-patents/scoreboard.html. Jaffe, Adam B. "The U.S. Patent System in Transition: Policy Innovation and the Innovative Process" (1999) NBER Working Paper No. W7280: Kortum, Samuel & Josh Lerner. "Stronger Protection or Technological Revolution: What is Behind the Recent Surge in Patenting?" (1997) NBER Working Paper No. W6204. Lerner, Josh. "150 Years of Patent Protection" (2000) NBER Working Paper No. W7478. - . "Where Does State Street Lead? A First Look at Finance Patents, 1971-2000" (2000) NBER Working Paper No. W7918. Levin, R . C , A . K . Klevorick, R.R. Nelson & S.G. Winter: "Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and Development" (1987) 3 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 783. Scotchmer, Susan. "Standing on the Shoulders of Giants: Cumulative Innovation and the Patent Law" (1991) 5 J. of Econ. Perspectives 29. '-. "Protecting Early Innovators: Should Second-Generation Products Be Patentable?" (1996) 27 Rand J. of Econ. 322. Quillen, Cecil D . , Jr. "Innovation and the United States Patent System Today," Presentation to the CLE Institute, Antitrust and Intellectual Property: Practice and Policy Issues for the 1990's (19 October 1992) available on-line at http://www.researchoninnovation.org/quillenl .pdf. —. "Proposal for the Simplification and Reform of the United States Patent System" (1993) 21 AIPLA Q.J. 189, also on-line at http://www.researchoninnovation.org/quillen2.pdf.  

Cite

Citation Scheme:

        

Citations by CSL (citeproc-js)

Usage Statistics

Share

Embed

Customize your widget with the following options, then copy and paste the code below into the HTML of your page to embed this item in your website.
                        
                            <div id="ubcOpenCollectionsWidgetDisplay">
                            <script id="ubcOpenCollectionsWidget"
                            src="{[{embed.src}]}"
                            data-item="{[{embed.item}]}"
                            data-collection="{[{embed.collection}]}"
                            data-metadata="{[{embed.showMetadata}]}"
                            data-width="{[{embed.width}]}"
                            async >
                            </script>
                            </div>
                        
                    
IIIF logo Our image viewer uses the IIIF 2.0 standard. To load this item in other compatible viewers, use this url:
http://iiif.library.ubc.ca/presentation/dsp.831.1-0077445/manifest

Comment

Related Items